The Best Laid Plans -- Planning and Affordable Housing in Marin
The End of Federal Housing
Programs
Call 'em NIMBYs
Ownership Will Save Us?
Bubble-nomics
Affordable Housing Today
What is Our Affordable
Housing Problem?
What Kinds of
Housing Do We Really Need in Marin?
The Law of Unintended
Consequences
It’s The Law?
A Cycle of Failure
Making Better Decisions
Looking Ahead
What Is the Problem
We’re Trying to Solve?
Housing Elements and Land
Entitlement
Affordable Housing Demand
Social Engineering at Its Worst
Workforce Housing
Nuts and Bolts and Finance
Affordable Housing and Social
Equity
Public Transportation and Growth
Local Voices Equal Better
Solutions
Leadership and New Directions
Working Collaboratively
APPENDICES
The Truth about
SB375 and the One Bay Area Plan
A
Criteria-Based Approach to Housing Policy for Mill Valley
Why “One Bay Area’s” Growth Plan is Not the Solution for Marin – Part I
Why “One Bay Area’s” Growth Plan is Not the Solution for Marin – Part II
An Alternative Analysis to the Development of Miller Avenue in Mill Valley
The Best Laid Plans - Part I: A Brief History of
Planning
“Adriana, if you stay here though, and this becomes your
present then pretty soon you'll start imagining another time was really
your... you know, was really the golden time.” ~ Midnight in Paris
– Woody Allen
In the late 1800’s, the social and economic disruptions caused by the
Industrial Revolution sparked a back-to-nature movement (inspired by the
writers like Thoreau) and utopian communities sprang up across the country.
But others believed that industrialization would bring about another kind of
utopia: one filled with scientific wonders and new opportunity for all. But
the dawning of the 20th Century brought surprises no one imagined.
The promise of the Industrial Revolution gave way to the financial panic of
1905 (when the federal government had to be bailed out by JP Morgan), the
war to end all wars (WWI), the Depression of 1921, the Roaring Twenties and
finally the Crash of 1929. The ensuing Great Depression left the public
shaken.
By 1933, life seemed like an unending litany of booms and busts and
scandals. Distrust of big business and government was at an all-time high.
The majority of wealth was controlled by a small percentage of the
population and the disparity between rich and poor had reached
historic proportions. And the political landscape had become increasingly
polarized on the left and the right.
Meanwhile, the general public was suffering from the worst real estate
crash in history and they just wanted someone to get people back to work.
Until the crash, people had been living high on the hog but now that seemed
gone forever. People were very angry and they wanted “change.”
Sound familiar? History seems to be repeating itself, for better and for
worse. But notwithstanding the years dedicated to fighting World War II, or
ironically because of it, in the decades that followed taxes got raised,
markets and finances were regulated, the middle class thrived, and the
American century came into its own. |
Pruitt Igoe Project Demolition – St. Louis, MO 1973 – HUD Archives |
A Very Brief History of City Planning
City planning has been with us forever. Alexandria, Athens, Rome, Tikal,
Paris and Washington, D.C., were all carefully planned, albeit from the very
top down. It’s even claimed that the reason Nero fiddled while Rome burned
was because he wanted to do major urban renewal and starting from scratch
was the best way to eliminate “community opposition.” But the planning of
our towns and cities (rather than seats of government) got a major boost
from the challenges of the early 20th century when a new idea was born.
From Bauhaus to Your House in Marin
There’s something about human nature that gravitates toward big,
simplistic solutions when faced with complex problems. And faced with the
multitude of woes in the
1930’s, many believed that massive housing projects were the way to solve
our social and economic problems.
This view was shared by many social reformers and prominent architects and
planners of the time, who proceeded to take a plausible idea and completely
overdo it. “Modern” architecture and planning, as it came to be known,
embraced mass production and technological innovation and promised to create
cities that showcased the wonders of the Industrial Age. This egalitarian
and utilitarian ideal, proselytized by Walter Gropius and the German
Bauhaus, was perhaps most famously expressed by an obscure painter
turned architect named Charles-Édouard Jeanneret (who changed his name to Le
Corbusier - perhaps being the first artist to take on a one name moniker).
The Radiant City
For “Modernists” like Corbusier, housing people was an
industrial undertaking and humanity’s needs were utilitarian (fresh air,
sunlight, sanitation, human scaled space, clean water and a view). This
culminated in a vision he called La Ville Radieuse (The Radiant
City). The Radiant City envisioned thousands of boxy, well lit,
unadorned living units stacked in towering glass, concrete and steel
skyscrapers built in close proximity to transportation (automotive super
highways) and within walking distance to shopping and other necessities
(“The more things change…”).
Unfortunately, grand visions tend to be doomed to grand failures.
To be fair, the modernists were as much driven by concern about public
health conditions for the 99 percent as they were by trying to house the
masses: there was little fresh air or natural light and few private
bathrooms in 19th century tenements and housing conditions for the
masses in general were abysmal. The times called for bold action and
optimism about grandiose solutions. Our innate love of all things new
and shiny proved irresistible.
So when our federal government looked for ways to solve the demand for
new housing in the 1940’s after WWII, they looked to Modernists'
visions. |
|
Projects like Stuyvesant Town / Peter Cooper Village
in New York City, built in 1947,
housed almost 100,000 people in one high density location (the Radiant
City in Manhattan). And the demand for housing at that time, after
decades of almost no housing construction, was very real.
Proponents claimed it had everything required to ensure its success.
It was a “walkable,” modern village close to schools, shopping and
public transportation. But what began in the late 40’s as a vision of
equality and affordable housing opportunity became a dystopian
nightmare, unflatteringly known as the "projects” by the 1960’s.
To have grown up in the projects was synonymous with having had a
deprived, crime-filled childhood that you dreamed of escaping. Somehow
“warehousing” people near public transportation and in walking
distance from shopping just didn’t magically bring about equality,
harmony or happiness.
Perhaps I’m just spit-balling here, but maybe it had something to do
with the complete lack of opportunity for individual expression and
other less tangible human
needs.
By the early 1970’s, these massive experiments in social engineering
had clearly failed and we began tearing down high density affordable
housing projects across the country. Pruitt Igoe in St. Louis (2,870
units; photo at top) was the most infamous but by no means the only
example. Yet somehow this lesson continues to escape the “one size
fits all” central planners today. |
|
By the 1980’s and early 1990’s, it became obvious
that we needed a new take on things. Fiscal conservatism became
the new fashion and federal funds for housing were drying up
faster than the Sacramento River Delta. Consequently, city
planning became more about urban renewal, historic preservation
and zoning codes than about building cities of the future. Left in
a lurch, planners swung 180 degrees in the other direction and
embraced the back-to-nature utopian ideals of the last century,
but this time with a new twist. This was a new kind of nostalgia
for the past that came wrapped in a new phrase:
“sustainable living.” It was called “New Urbanism.”
Towns would now instantly have all the “character” of small town
Americana. New
Urbanism preached the benefits of walkable communities
near shopping, amenities and public transportation. It was based
on observing successful small towns (like our towns in Marin)
and attempted to reproduce the lifestyle they enjoyed. The only
problem is there’s a lot more to what creates “community” than
meets the eye. |
|
New Urbanism envisioned winding streets lined with
quaint Craftsman-like clapboard homes on small lots, with people
chatting with neighbors from rocking chairs on wooden porches
behind white picket fences. Neighborhoods were laid out around
quaint “town squares” with housing districts separated from
commercial areas by green space. In many ways these plans were
almost an exact copy of the utopian towns that were designed and
built in the U.S. from the late 1800’s and the early 20th
century.
There’s no argument that there are compelling reasons for living
in a more humanized environment. Just ask anyone who lives in
Marin. But at the end of the day, the New Urbanism vision is
superficial and its “community” is as faux as the shiplap siding
on its cutesy bungalows.
New Urbanism is like Ralph Lauren was in the 1980’s. Both
try to sell us a nostalgic, patina-tinged vision of a past that
never actually existed. Rather than doing the hard work of
rethinking our world from the bottom up, addressing
inter-related socio- economic realities and offering a truly new
vision of our future potential, New Urbanism offers us a
sentimental throwback to a Norman Rockwell painting belief about
who we are. But in the face of our 21st Century challenges, it’s
devoid of sustainable answers because we are not those imaginary
people and we don’t live those imaginary lives. New Urbanism
planners have made their careers out of selling a vision of
simpler times to a world-weary public. But in reality, the
promises of New Urbanism are empty. |
|
Interestingly, New Urbanism was originally conceived to
improve upon and make some sense out of suburban sprawl. It is
actually mislabeled. It should be called “suburban-renewal.” It
primarily focused on better ways to build single family housing in
places completely devoid of character (Laguna West near
Sacramento, Denver Stapleton Airport Redevelopment, etc.) and
hoped that suburban commuters would someday be served by better
transportation options like light rail.
These were perfectly legitimate goals. But New Urbanism
wanted to get people out of cars mostly to enhance social
interaction and small town character, not because of presumptuous
claims about mitigating climate change. Likewise, New Urbanism
was not originally about affordable housing. But in an attempt to
remain relevant, it has been turned to the
dark side.
Planners like Peter Calthorpe now work for major suburban
developers like Forest City Enterprises, and New Urbanism
has become synonymous with social engineering by big government
agencies promoting infill, high density housing near freeways.
This unfortunate fusion has given us what might be described as
the worst of both dystopian worlds: the faux “sustainable”
community of the “back to simpler times” movement combined with
the high density near transportation / housing for the masses
visions of the Modernists. And in the middle, real communities
like ours in Marin, which were built on decades of local control
and environmental protection, are being thrown under the bus in
the name of progress.
The result is projects like the 180-unit WinCup development,
located next to the 101 highway off ramps in Corte Madera,
and the Millworks mixed use project in Novato (Whole Foods
and condos). Building projects like this as “infill” won’t make
them work any better than their larger scaled predecessors. It’s a
sure bet that in 20 years these will not be among the most
desirable places to live in Marin.
Perhaps the most absurd irony of all though is that we now have
Peter Calthorpe coming to Marin to preach to us about the virtues
of New Urbanism when in fact it is towns like ours that were the
inspiration for New Urbanism in the first place.
I think our citizens know better than anyone what “community” and
“walkable neighborhoods” and “small town character” are. The
New Urbanism planners of the world should be coming to
Marin to learn not to preach. We don’t need their definition
of “sustainable” but they sure do need ours. Yet we find ourselves
having to fight against the New Urbanist
mantra to preserve what we have: the very thing they
profess to want to create. Figure that one out.
In truth, New Urbanism’s solutions are not really more
sustainable. Their greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions savings are
nonexistent (Appendix A).
Their building methods are conventional and just as
environmentally destructive as anything else. And implementing its
concepts without first addressing the underlying social and
economic causes of social inequity is fiscally irresponsible.
Who’s not for
a Sustainable Future?
Let’s face it. Everyone is for “sustainable solutions.” But
those solutions need to actually be socially, economically and
environmentally sustainable after considering their true costs of
“natural capital” and their external affects (supply chain energy
usage, third world environmental degradation, etc.; also see
Natural Capitalism by Paul Hawken). New Urbanism and
the One Bay Area Plan approach are not that. What we really
need are solutions that are truly environmentally sustainable
and address our social equity challenges at the same time. We
need solutions that make fiscal sense for our cities and financial
sense to private capital markets.
That is the problem before us. But instead we find ourselves faced
with an unappetizing menu of “high density” options and massive
bureaucracies trying to force one size fits all solutions down our
throats (Appendix
C), none of which are really sustainable in any real sense of
the word.
But there was a third vision that came out of the 1930’s that was
totally ignored in its day and has been derided by historians ever
since. Its author was not a popular man. He was the quintessential
“politically incorrect” designer of his time. But it was the only
vision that actually addressed long term sustainability. Maybe
there are things we can learn from it.
Photo Credits The Radiant City – Wikipedia
Foundation Stuyvesant Town / Peter Cooper Village – Wikipedia
Foundation Seaside, Florida – Seaside Marketing Brochure
Stapleton Redevelopment – Forest City Development
The Best Laid
Plans - Part II: 21st Century Planning
“The Internet is based on a layered, end to end
model that allows people at each level of the network to
innovate free of any central control. By placing intelligence
at the edges rather than control in the middle of the network,
the Internet has created a platform for innovation.”
~ Vint Cerf
When you develop Internet software, the only thing you can
be sure of is that everything you’re sure of will probably
change because innovation is happening everywhere in the long
tail. It is the ultimate “bottom up” system. This means that
designing for it requires solutions that embrace user
interactivity, open-ended design, flexibility, and methods
that “learn” and adapt to change. I think city planning can be
that way. In fact I think it will have to be because whether
we like it or not, the coming century will be an increasingly
bottom up, networked, borderless, telecommuting, personally
expressive, crowd-sourced world.
I know. It sounds like a lot of big words. But think about it.
I recently wrote a piece about a “criteria-based method” of
planning (Appendix
B). It suggests an approach that would be more responsive
and adaptable to the nuances of local public policy needs and
the ever-changing dynamics of private capital markets. It
highlights the importance of enabling individual initiative
and local empowerment in solving planning problems. And in
some ways it was inspired by the third planning vision that
came out of the 1930’s. |
Broadacre City, 1935 – Frank Lloyd Wright Foundation |
The Bad Boy of
Planning
Frank Lloyd Wright was perhaps the most controversial
architect in modern history. His iconoclastic career was unique
even among American visionaries. Always the rebel, he never
bothered to get a license to practice until he was in his 70's,
by which time he'd designed or built more than 600 buildings. By
today’s standards he’d be called a Libertarian (footnote: The
Marin County Civic Center was Wright's last commission before
his death).
Wright absolutely hated top down planning and big government.
He’d be rolling over in his grave if he knew about ABAG
(Association of Bay Area Governments) and One Bay Area Plan.
When it came to city planning, Wright was a staunch advocate of
“local control.”
Wright called his planning vision Broadacre
City. Like the other planning concepts of the Depression
Era, its goals were to enhance the fortunes of the common
man by creating a more egalitarian society. But after that
it diverged completely from the orthodoxy of Modern urbanism
because it wasn’t urban at all.
Universally dismissed by critics of the time, it turned out
to be the most durable idea of all because it foresaw the
rise of suburbia. In fact it has been blamed for all the
ills of suburbia but that’s just because Broadacre City’s
concept was never fully understood or appreciated.
Unlike the Modernist’s high-density, glass and concrete
cities or utopianism’s back to nature schemes, Broadacre
City might be called the "40 acres and a mule" school of
planning. Wright aimed for a balance between nature and
man’s footprint on the planet. He was a strong proponent of
individual creativity and personal self-sufficiency long
before it was fashionably called “sustainable.”
Wright envisioned an adaptive plan wherein every family had
its own sustainable one acre plot, large enough to grow some
food, capture rainwater, have a windmill and raise a few
animals. He envisioned "growth" as an organic process that
was mostly horizontal, with occasional instances of high
rise development (his famous “mile-high” skyscraper design
being an example of that). |
|
Now there’s no doubt that Wright’s ideas were in some
ways even more fanciful than the other planning visions of
his time. But Wright was essentially talking about living
"off the grid" or at least not being dominated by it. Like
the way the Internet is managed today, he was talking about
planning that had no central control point but was designed
and developed by local
users for local
conditions “at the edges,” all within a flexible framework
that optimized outcomes for all. In this respect, he was way
ahead of his time.
Technology
and Sustainability
SB 375 and the One Bay Area Plan approach tell us
that we have to accept the Modernist / New Urbanism high
density near public transportation vision of the future. The
argument is based on claims about mitigating environmental
impacts. It's a rigid and single-minded view of the future
in which suburban living is singled out as a major problem.
But it's not based on facts.
As I've shown before, their greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions
savings assumptions are seriously flawed (Appendix
A), and they incorrectly assume that the things we make
(our vehicles, buildings, appliances, etc.) are immutable
givens that will never change.
This is the basis for their GHG calculations and rationale.
But there’s no evidence that this is true or even likely in
the future.
Vertical, high-density cities are not, in and of themselves,
a sustainable solution. They are an "economic" solution and
perhaps a "social" solution. But today, cities like New York
City are, on a per capita basis, the most egregious
polluters on the planet, not just in terms of GHG emissions
but also when one accounts for all the impacts on
surrounding regions to “feed” them with water and power and
deal with their waste. And regarding
SB375’s assumptions about polluting automobiles, vehicle
technology not only can change but it is
changing dramatically as we speak (the 2013 Ford C-Max
Energi is a plug-in hybrid that will get more than 110 mpg).
All this considered, shouldn’t we be planning for the future
instead of the past?
New technology offers us other options. The ability to
produce zero pollution and super energy-efficient vehicles,
buildings and mechanical equipment is within our reach. It
only requires national, state and local public policy to
make it happen (just as agri-business and oil and gas
subsidies make those things happen). But there is another
"elephant in the room" that is not even acknowledged by the
One Bay Area approach, though it may be even more
important than all the rest.
Power,
Water and Waste Systems
Achieving a sustainable future and “planning for change”
also includes how we distribute power and water and collect
and process waste. Throughout history the need to share and
efficiently distribute resources from a central location
(e.g. water from a river or natural spring) has been a
given. This is so ingrained in our thinking that we accept
it without questioning its long term sustainability
challenges. But by all measures centralized utility systems
are incredibly wasteful and inefficient. This gets even
worse in suburbia where the distances between users and the
sources of power or water or the distance to sewage
treatment plants is greater.
Significant losses occur as electrical power moves out
through our vast centralized power grids. A large percentage
of our drinking water is lost due to leakage and evaporation
as it moves through underground pipes and aqueducts. And in
many U.S. metropolitan areas, 50 percent of the effluent
that goes into sewer lines never reaches the treatment plant
because it leaches out into the ground through old pipes.
And then there’s the cost of building and maintaining these
centralized systems and the support services, which create
even more pollution and waste.
When it comes to really addressing our environmental
challenges and the host of options at hand, all this becomes
very important to consider because efficient use of
resources is fundamental to any environmentally or
economically sustainable solution. So we have to ask
ourselves, is there a better way? And if there is, what
model should we be looking to for guidance?
The Nature of Nature
The history of the world is the history of going from
simplicity to diversity, from single-celled organisms to
multi-celled marvels, and from isolated linear systems
to complex inter-related networks and “systems of
systems.” Throughout that process, nature’s
problem-solving methods have favored bottom up and
locally driven solutions that allow for the nuances and
constraints of local conditions.
But there are more benefits to nature’s way than
respecting local control and encouraging diversity.
Nature’s top-to-bottom and bottom-to-top interactive
feedback methods tend to result in solutions that are
the most energy, time and resource efficient possible
for all participants. Because of real-time interactivity
between local and global, nature’s methods are
constantly optimizing outcomes for all.
Consider three examples: the way your brain is wired,
how a vine grows on a fence and the infrastructure of
the Internet.
Each is elegantly adapted to solve “local” problems
in a way that addresses specific needs, and at the same
time allow the entire networked “organism” to operate as
efficiently as possible without central control. This is
the secret of their success. |
|
21st Century Interactive Planning
City planning has followed the same trajectory as
nature, evolving from enclosed city states into networks
of cities separated by vast expanses, until the edges of
cities expanded to the point where everything got
connected and we have the megalopolis we live in today:
networks of inter-related entities with both shared
concerns and unique problems. But we’re at a tipping point
in history. The top-down, centrally controlled state and
regional planning methods that made sense in the past are
now too rigid and unresponsive to address the complexity
of our contemporary world.
Looking ahead, what we need are methods that enhance
greater interaction between the top and the bottom,
maximize local input and local control of planning
decisions, and encourage diverse and novel solutions. The
implications of this for our political process, legal
framework and planning hierarchies are enormous.
Interactivity even suggests the need for our
representative form of government to finally transform
into a "one person, one vote" true democracy.
This brings us back to Frank Lloyd Wright. It's important
to recognize that the fundamental limitations of Wright’s
sustainable concepts were technological. The technology
required to make his ideas feasible simply didn’t exist.
However, today we have the ability to realize Wright’s
self-sufficiency and environmental / community /
sustainability goals.
In the near future every vehicle we produce will be
pollution free and run on sustainable power (electricity,
hydrogen, biofuels, etc.), and every building could be
carbon neutral and produce most of its own power. And
buildings could harvest and recycle grey water and treat
much of their waste on site (see photos).
Consider the following:
Water: Water conserving appliances and
equipment, drip irrigation, rainwater capture and gray
water recycling can dramatically reduce the amount of
water needed and force us to rethink our water
distribution methods (this is already
happening enough to
put the Marin Municipal Water District’s business model in
jeopardy).
Waste: “Closed-loop” waste technology
that separates and treats waste on site has been around
for more than 40 years. It's time that this was given more
careful consideration. These systems can greatly reduce
the need to expand or upgrade sewer systems and can
increase the opportunities to produce recycled waste
products. Recycling and banning plastic bags is just the
tip of the iceberg of the change that is possible when it
comes to dealing with our trash.
Energy: Advances in energy-conserving
products and alternative energy sources are about to tip
the balance of global energy production and distribution
from the top to the bottom. Feeding power in one direction
out to users on the grid, from central power plants (i.e.
hydroelectric plants, nuclear reactors, coal fired
generators, etc.) is technologically obsolete. “Smart
Grids” distribute power the
way the Internet distributes information and
dramatically alter the “user / producer” relationship.
They change a “distribution” network into a “sharing”
network where everyone becomes both a user and a producer.
New thin-film photovoltaics can produce solar energy on
any surface (even window glass). Wind is the fastest
growing new energy source in the world and residential,
rooftop wind generators should start showing up at Home
Depot within the next decade. More options will be here
sooner than people think especially if we encourage them.
As Amory Lovins
has so famously said, it’s all about “reduce, reuse,
recycle.” Every product we manufacture needs to address
its energy consumption and waste output and be
100 percent recyclable. This is true for the buildings
we build, the vehicles we drive, the food we grow, and the
gadgets we consume with abandon (it's called "Cradle to
Cradle" design). Even things like urban farming are
transforming our cities and demonstrating the efficiencies
of solving "demand" problems at the source.
But again, this won’t happen without public will and
public policy to support it. So if our government is going
to provide financial incentives for anything, perhaps this
is money better spent than the hundreds of billions we
spend annually subsidizing military arms, oil and coal,
and sugar and corn.
What Does This Have To Do With Planning?
All this suggests that future growth may be much more
about renovation, reuse, conservation and technologically
retrofitting what we already have (like putting rooftop
solar on every building) than about “scrape and build”
construction and the grandiose planning methods that
dominated the 20th century. This is not science fiction.
These are the things we have to do if we ever hope to
offer the next generation a reasonable future. And if even
half of what I’m suggesting comes to pass, it will have
profound implications for the future of planning.
If adaptive technology can re-engineer our lives and
automobiles will no longer pollute or rely on fossil
fuels, then all the "urban" versus "suburban" arguments
fall apart. In fact lower density suburban solutions may
have significant environmental and quality of life
advantages over high density urban solutions. At the very
least, there’s room for a wide variety of locally driven
solutions, all of which might be equally sustainable and
all of which should be on the table for consideration
instead of the one-sided thinking we’re being force-fed by state and regional agencies (ABAG/MTC/BCDC/BAAQMD).
Solving
Problems at the Source
I live in a 1,830-square-foot house on a 50 by 125 ft.
lot. I have landscaped yards with six kinds of fruit trees
and a sizeable vegetable garden, all fed by automated drip
irrigation. I compost most organic waste and produce very
little trash. I drive a hybrid car. My appliances and
fixtures are energy saving and low flow. My electric bill
averages less than $90 per month. For almost that same
monthly cost, on a leased basis, I’m considering
installing solar panels which
would provide 100 percent of my electrical needs now and
when I purchase a plug-in electric
car in the future. If I had a
rainwater capture and grey
water waste recycling system, I’d pretty much be
off the grid, or in the case
of electricity, selling back to the grid.
Someone please explain to me how this is not a
sustainable solution.
Someone please explain to me why we’re not creating every
incentive we can to allow everyone to
renovate and retrofit their homes to
live this way, or why all new residential
(single family and multifamily) and commercial buildings
shouldn’t be designed to have far less environmental
impact (LEED – Leadership in Energy and Environmental
Design - is not enough). Public policy supporting this
would create thousands of new businesses and tens of
millions of 21st century hi-tech jobs across the country
(versus short term, low pay construction and service
jobs).
Why is it we're not hearing anything about these options
from ABAG / MTC and our elected officials? Have we
really become that unimaginative or that pessimistic about
our future? How can we expect anything to change if we
don’t bring about change right here in our own
communities? Do we really want to bet our future on the
dismal, over-reaching plans of engorged government
agencies?
The arguments that "urban" is good and "suburban" is
bad, or "high density" is superior to "low density" are
off base. Our path to a better future is through solving
problems in the most efficient and mutually beneficial way
possible. And I believe that it's the right combination of
financial backstop from the top and locally driven public
policy and decision making at the bottom that can best
ensure that outcome.
Looking Ahead
Myopic high-density scenarios like the One Bay Area
Plan are out of synch with the multi-faceted way the
future of our cities and infrastructure is likely to
unfold. It deals in fixed absolutes and views things from
only one direction: producers to users, sellers to buyers.
Jobs and workers are just numbers devoid of human
proclivities and choice. It fails to account for our
increasingly interactive world and how creative, private
capital and public policy changes can dramatically effect
predictions based on the status quo.
This is particularly critical right now because don't have
the luxury of unlimited resources or unlimited wealth to
squander on bad ideas. The faulty assumptions of laws like
SB375
(Appendix A) will lead to more bad decisions and more
misallocation of taxpayer money. And applying its faulty
logic to other challenges, like affordable housing,
has already led to even more damaging proposals like
SB1220 (more local taxes and fewer local benefits)
and SB226
(eliminating CEQA review for "infill" projects),
which undermines the very thing SB375 pretends to
be trying to preserve, our environment.
It’s a road we cannot afford to go down.
Over-reaching top-down social engineering has failed us in
the past and it will fail us again. Its approach is
economically destabilizing and financially irresponsible
because it contradicts the laws of supply and demand, free
markets, and the way communities naturally grow and
thrive. And it’s ultimately environmentally destructive.
And for what?
But if all that’s true, then how do we address our
legitimate social justice and affordable housing concerns?
And what about the portion of our population that is truly
in great need, the people we really should be focusing on
who are just getting by and need a helping hand or a
“safety net” right now?
Photo Credits Broadacre City – Frank Lloyd
Wright Brain Synapse – Scientific American Vine on Fence –
Public Domain Internet Layout – Public Domain
The Best
Laid Plans - Part III: Affordable Housing
“Those who cannot remember the past are
condemned to repeat it.” ~ George
Santayana
When I was growing up in New York City, where my
family owned a small business, my father told me that
the scariest words in the English language were,
“We're from the government and we're here to help
you." A lot of people feel that way about ABAG
housing quotas and
affordable housing projects
in general. But it’s more complicated than that.
Reasonable people might agree that having a variety of
housing opportunities for those most in need, without
discrimination, is a worthy societal goal. But there’s
a difference between “providing housing opportunities”
and “building affordable housing.” And affordable
housing means different things to different people in
different places. It includes homeless shelters,
starter homes, rental apartments and townhouses,
live/work lofts, SRO (single room occupancy) housing,
elderly housing and assisted living, housing for very
low and low income (below 30 percent to 50 percent
median) and 80 percent median income “affordable”
units like the ones we see being built all over Marin
(for a family in Mill Valley earning about
$90,000 per year).
So where should we focus our efforts and how do we
define and prioritize our needs? Some history of how
we got here helps. |
Dexter Asylum (Poor House), Providence RI 1824
- Library of Congress |
A Brief History of Affordable Housing
Affordable housing in the U.S. was traditionally left
to private markets or corporations that built “company
towns” for their workers (e.g. Pullman, Illinois (see
photo) and Scotia, California). But the idea that the
government should get directly involved (other than
operating “poor houses” for the destitute; see photo)
didn’t really come into being until the Great
Depression.
In 1934, the National Housing Act created the
Federal Housing Administration (FHA) to help people
protect their homes from foreclosure. The 1937
Housing Act, which coined the phrase “affordable
housing,” subsidized the construction of
government-owned rental housing for the general public
under Section 8 of the Act. After that the
federal government quickly became the primary driver of
affordable housing construction and finance.
The mid 1940’s through the early 1960’s was the Golden
Age of government housing. The 1949 Housing Act
and urban renewal legislation caused a building boom
across the country to feed post World War II demand.
Projects like Stuyvesant Town / Peter Cooper Village in
New York City, built by a “public–private partnership”
in 1947, housed almost 100,000 people in one location
(see Part I).
The Winds of Change
The 1960’s saw the passage of Fair Housing laws to
ensure equal access to housing, an important
advancement. But in the aftermath of the Vietnam War the
nation turned more conservative. The costs of the war
and Johnson’s Great Society had been enormous. One of
Richard Nixon’s first actions as president in 1970 was
to cut federal housing programs dramatically. The
thinking was that we were sinking too deeply into debt
and could no longer afford them.
To replace some of the financial shortfall, the
Community Development Block Grants program was
created in 1974 and modifications were made to
Section 8 housing programs to allow low income
renters to live in privately owned buildings. Signed by
Gerald Ford, these changes eliminated a good number of
government-built public housing programs so construction
started shifting back to the private sector. These were
the first substantive changes since the 1930’s. But the
real turning point came when Ronald Reagan was elected
in 1980. This marked the beginning of the end of HUD’s
central role in providing affordable housing and the
beginning of the “markets can solve everything”
mantra.
The End of Federal Housing Programs
One of Reagan’s stated goals was to get the federal
government out of the housing business completely, and
so the systematic dismantling of affordable housing
support systems began in earnest. In 1983, a
Reagan-appointed commission recommended an end to all
project-based Section 8 subsidies, except in the case of
rehabilitation. They recommended that all subsidies
shift to housing vouchers to give private
developers incentive to build affordable housing
(vouchers are a rental payment coupon that a renter can
use to live anywhere). No new government-owned housing
projects were approved for construction after Reagan’s
election.
Jack Kemp, a self-described “bleeding heart
conservative” and arguably one of the most important
architects of HUD’s recent history, became
Secretary of HUD in 1989. Prior to that, he worked
behind the scenes to help the Reagan Administration
“privatize” the affordable housing business.
Co-insurance, wherein private banks took over the role
of financing projects in exchange for government
guarantees of their debt, became widely used. Housing
“project revenue bonds” and leverage debt became
fashionable methods to finance private development
without personal risk. And newly created Low Income
Tax Credits attracted investment banking, mutual
fund and corporate money to fund projects that had
federal Housing Assistance Payments (HAP) Contracts
in place to guarantee high rents.
This all worked great for a while until unscrupulous
underwriting practices and too much leveraged debt
brought on the Savings & Loan Crisis in the
1980’s (which we have to thank for coining the phrase
“too big to fail”). When it was over,
multifamily development was
stalled for years and the banking fiasco became
another excuse to get rid of
government housing programs altogether.
The Knock-Out Punch
In the final coup d’état, the Office of
Independent Council launched a massive investigation
into “political influence peddling” at HUD in
1988. The investigation was based on the “shocking”
revelation that subsidy grant decisions in Washington
might be influenced by political favoritism and high
paid lobbyists (OMG, there’s “gambling at Rick’s”). This
seems quaint today and it had little to do with routing
out corruption, but secretaries went to jail while high
rollers walked away scot free. And federal affordable
housing programs never recovered.
Project-based subsidies (projects with HAP contracts)
were greatly reduced. Co- insurance and renovation
programs like the Moderate Rehabilitation program were
scuttled. And all that was left were Section 8
vouchers and tentative annual allocations of Low
Income Tax Credits that almost exclusively went to
big nonprofit developers who resold them to major
corporations and investment funds. But as bad as all
this was, it was only the beginning.
Call 'em NIMBYs
In 1991, HUD issued a report entitled, “Not
in My Back Yard – The Advisory Commission on Regulatory
Barriers to Affordable Housing.” Authored by Jack
Kemp and signed by George Bush, Sr., it came to be known
as the “NIMBY REPORT.” The NIMBY Report alleged that
local planning and zoning control
was an impediment to affordable housing
development and had to be challenged (this is the same
position that ABAG / MTC / Plan Bay Area and,
ironically, left-leaning social reformers like the
Marin Community Foundation are advancing today).
But we have to ask ourselves, why would neo-con
Republican politicians propose such a liberal Democratic
sounding idea? Was it because of genuine concern for the
needy? Having personally had a front row seat to watch
the goings on at HUD in Washington, D.C., at the
time, I can say with confidence that it wasn’t. To bring
their ideological motives into relief, we need only swap
the terms “affordable housing development” with “developer profits” and it becomes
clear what the elimination of impediments was all about.
By the early 1990’s, it was obvious that vouchers, Jack
Kemp’s pet program, had failed to increase the
affordable housing supply as promised (without direct
government subsidy contracts, projects no longer
“penciled”). And as the market weakness of the early
1990’s gave way to a new building boom, developers
needed more entitled land - and fast. The NIMBY
Report, a pro-markets,
pro-private developer profits, and pro-big banking
campaign thinly camouflaged as an affordable housing
policy, has been the rallying cry of affordable
housing advocates ever since (who are apparently
oblivious as to its origins).
This pro-development agenda formed the philosophical
basis for the kinds of “straw man” arguments we’re
dealing with today. Resistance to any affordable housing
project in Marin, no matter how ill-conceived, is
immediately labeled NIMBY. But perhaps the
resistance to affordable housing in Marin is less about
NIMBYism than it is about the increasing loss of local
control and community choice in how our communities grow
and cope financially, and how we maintain our quality of
life.
Ownership Will
Save Us?
In 1994, the Government Accounting Office
continued the assault on federally funded housing
programs with a report that damned HUD for its
wastefulness (never mind
that HUD’s total budget was a mere fraction of the U.S.
budgets for defense, farm subsidy, oil subsidy, or other
heavily lobbied line items). Subsequently, a bill was
introduced in the House of Representatives in 1995 to
permanently shut HUD down. It almost passed. Then in
1997, Congress removed the last linchpin of affordable
housing law passed in 1937 that required the federal
government to replace every affordable unit it tore down
or put out of use.
From the mid-1990’s onward, the affordable housing
business remained a shadow of its former self. The new
focus was home ownership, not rentals, probably because
in a “more debt / more leverage” financial system driven
by the lure of lucrative underwriting fees, the mortgage
brokers, banks and investment bankers could “game” that
system more profitably than the rental housing business
(many multifamily funding loopholes were closed after
the S&L crisis).
Then in 2003 Congress passed the “American Dream Down
Payment Initiative” and the already inflating
housing bubble started to expand more rapidly, and
affordability went out the window. We became focused on
the wonders of price appreciation as the solutions to
all our social equity problems. We know how that turned
out.
Bubble-nomics
By 2007, it’s estimated that more than
40 percent of new jobs
being created annually in California were
real estate related
(finance, banking, mortgage underwriting, construction,
materials, real estate sales, household furnishings,
appliances, supporting services, gardeners, house
cleaning and everything they sell at Home Depot). With
stiff environmental regulations dating back to the 1970s
standing in their way and housing demand skyrocketing,
real estate development interests continued to worry
about land scarcity and lengthy entitlement processes.
They needed to “feed the beast.” The California State
Legislature came to their rescue (and has been coming to
their rescue ever since).
“Affordable housing” green-washed with climate change
“concerns” was the perfect argument to defeat opposition
and look like heroes doing it. Following the passage of
AB32 and fueled by the financial backing of
moneyed special interest groups, Senator Darrell
Steinberg crafted
SB375 (drafted in 2005 and signed into law in
September of 2008 just weeks before the crash).
SB375 capitalized on the “NIMBY” argument and
added climate change as a new reason to usurp local
zoning control, even though its claims of greenhouse gas
emissions reductions are unsubstantiated (Appendix
A). With the last obstacles to development swept
away it looked like clear sailing into an endless
building boom. The 2008 crash changed everything.
The unsustainable levels of public and private debt that
fueled the boom have brought on the worst financial
crisis in more than 50 years. Cities that over-extended
themselves by building more and more housing ended up
broke and may never recover (Vallejo, Modesto, Fresno,
Stockton, etc.). The fantasy that building housing
without prerequisite job growth is a path to a better
economic future has been totally discredited. But never
underestimate the power of a bad idea.
Affordable
Housing Today
As it stands today, we really have no cohesive or
financially sustainable national affordable housing
programs. Federal funding assistance for affordable
housing of any kind is pathetically low. Federal Low
Income Housing Tax Credits only offer about $5
billion in annual assistance (Goldman Sachs will pay out
about 3 times that amount this year in executive
bonuses). Section 8 vouchers only cover about 2
million households at a time when the latest census
indicates that 1 in 4 families live at or below the
poverty level. Meanwhile local governments are left to
fight for table scraps as the state and federal
government take more in taxes and fees and give back
less.
Today, we have “in lieu” development where at best we
get 1 or 2 so-called affordable units developed for
every 8 or 9 market rate homes built (about half are for
80 percent median income, which is not all that
affordable). But the negative impacts of these projects
on traffic, infrastructure, tax base, schools, the
environment and everything else far outweigh the
benefits. We occasionally get some projects funded
through grants, but these have been only marginally
successful (e.g., the Mill Valley Fireside
apartments) because the reasons for developing them are
too skewed away from the reality of market economics and
real demand.
We’re told there’s not enough money, that the country
can’t afford it. But that’s only true because our
spending priorities are completely out of whack (i.e.
development of the new F-35 fighter jet is estimated to
cost us $1 trillion dollars over the next decade). In
addition, the affordable housing
development game is now so rigged in favor of large
nonprofit developers that creative private capital is
pretty much excluded. And going forward, private capital
participation will be essential.
What is Our Affordable Housing Problem?
There’s little question that more federal funding
would help provide financial incentives to local
governments and private development interests trying to
address affordable housing challenges. The trickle of
funding available now is just not enough. But before we
start “throwing money” at the “problem” we need to be
sure what we’re trying
to accomplish.
Today’s affordable housing challenges are very different
from the real market demand for housing that followed
the Great Depression and World War II. At that time,
there had been no housing built in decades and there was
a (baby) boom in population and household formation.
Today we have just the opposite.
We have a glut of housing across the state
but much of it is not located
where jobs are. And while traditional jobs are
scarce, many newer jobs go begging because of the lack
of trained candidates in the labor pool. In addition,
net migration in California
is negative: more people are
moving out than moving in.
Marin has experienced stagnant population and jobs
growth over the past 20 years. And
ironically, the Housing Affordability Index is at a
record high. On a tax-adjusted, cash flow basis it’s
never been cheaper to own a home. So where’s the
affordable housing problem?
Our problem today is only similar to the Depression and
its aftermath in that it’s more about economic
dysfunction and our failure to create an equitable
society where real opportunity exists for all. Our
problem is that while corporate profits and CEO
paychecks are at historic highs,
average wages, in real inflation-adjusted terms, have
lagged so far behind the cost of living, and personal
savings are so depleted, that even middle class people
can’t afford to buy a home (much less low income
people). On the other hand, rents are rising because so
little rental housing was built in the past two decades.
So housing options are squeezed for everyone and those
most in need suffer disproportionately.
It’s obvious that unless we address our underlying
social equity and economic problems, there will be no
end to our “housing” problems. But there are still a lot
of things we could be doing at a local level.
What Kinds of Housing Do We Really Need in Marin?
Quotas and mandates have clouded our
thinking. Instead of counting units we should be asking
what types of housing we really need. In many Marin
communities, demographic trends show that we have an
underserved need for many types of affordable housing
that we hear little about in the media. These include:
-
• Housing for
the elderly and assisted living facilities.
• Housing for people with disabilities and special
medical needs.
• Homeless shelters and abused women's safe houses.
• Live/work opportunities like lofts and cooperative
housing.
• Co-housing, where residents design and/or operate
their own hybrid housing solutions (the ultimate in
local control).
• Apartment building preservation, reconfiguration and
substantial rehabilitation.
• Building conversions from commercial to mixed use
residential.
• Sweat equity opportunities where residents can buy
unfinished space to finish out themselves.
• Very small starter rental and condo units for
singles and young couples (as small as 650 sq. ft. two
story).
• Smaller single family housing for the “active
elderly” (partially retired and very active but not
wanting any maintenance obligations).
The list is long. So let’s ask
ourselves, how many of
these kinds of projects are we actually getting built
using our present process?
The answer is none.
The Law of Unintended Consequences
Ironically, the more laws we pass to try to force
zoning changes to enable high density residential
development, the more creative, mixed use / adaptive
use local solutions are “crowded
out” of the market. With our planning tools
(Housing Elements, zoning bonuses, site designation
lists, fast track processing, etc.) radically skewed
to support over- sized, high density in-lieu schemes,
affordable housing development has become a game where
those are the only projects that get considered,
whether or not they make financial sense, community
sense, common sense or there’s any real market demand
for them. Creative capital investors have no incentive
to even try to fill our real housing needs (listed
above) and even if we could get these kinds of
projects built, most wouldn’t be counted as against
our ABAG quotas.
Yet Sacramento’s social engineers and ABAG
planners and some of our elected representatives seem
oblivious to these kinds of
unintended consequences. Residents are
increasingly being bullied into capitulation about
quotas and requirements because they’re told “it’s the
law.” But as anyone who has actually read the
prevailing mishmash of governing laws can attest, the
implementation of “the law” in this case is anything
but clear cut and is open to a variety of
interpretations. And there are certainly enough gray
areas to mount good arguments for
local solutions. But the
problem is that everywhere we look we only seem to be
hearing one interpretation of the law: the one that
most benefits special interests.
It’s fairly obvious that Marin
has many more opportunities for infill, mixed-use
renovation projects with affordable units included
than we do for “high density near public
transportation.” So why aren’t we doing
everything we can to help that happen instead of
continuing to promote unneeded
market rate, in-lieu development?
It’s The Law?
As debates about local planning, Housing Elements,
General Plan updates and affordable housing heat up,
it is increasingly important that the public be given
the full story about what is or is not “the law.” But
this isn’t always the case.
In Mill Valley, for example, the community has been
told for years, by our Planning Department, that we
are required to adopt provisions that provide for
30 units per acre zoning:
our default density for
affordable housing development because we’re
designated an “urban” area by HCD (Housing and
Community Development). This clearly
favors large-scaled development.
This was their justification for recommending approval
of Planned Development (PD), high density
projects on Miller Avenue. These recommendations also
came with a variety of floor area ratio (FAR) bonuses,
and building setback, height and parking variances
because 10 percent of their
units were affordable.
This single issue about site density has been the
basis of endless battles and hundreds of hours of time
at public meetings. It has created enormous community
ill will and it’s even driven some well-intended
affordable housing developers with more modest
schemes, to give up and walk away. But it turns out
that it’s not even true.
According to the HCD Housing Policy Development
regulations on minimum densities for the Housing
Element and the appurtenant regulations, Mill Valley’s
default density is just 20 units per acre not 30. The
regulations state that: "Jurisdictions
(cities/counties) located within a Metropolitan
Statistical Area (MSA) with a population of more than
2 million as listed below (Alameda, Contra Costa, Los
Angeles, Marin, Orange, Riverside, San Bernardino, San
Diego, San Francisco, and San Mateo - are “urban”)
unless a city / county has a population of less than
25,000” in which case it would be exempt from that
requirement and be governed by the law’s minimums,
which is noted as 20 units per acre.
I suspect the community is dealing with this kind of
thing in other cities in Marin and at the county
level.
For example, op-ed pieces in the Marin IJ
regularly admonish us about our need to comply with
every rule and RHNA allocation that ABAG /
HCD hands us or risk onerous penalties, law suits
and loss of funding. Yet as Carla Condon,
councilmember from Corte Madera, explained in
great detail at a recent
Marin Communities Coalition for Local Control
meeting, this just isn’t true. No city can be
denied funding for which they are otherwise eligible
just because they are in a disagreement with ABAG or
HCD about how
to interpret their legal obligations. A city is only
obligated to create a Housing Element and get it
certified within a specified period of time. And the
kinds of “urban development”
grants that are supposedly at risk have never be
available to small cities in Marin anyway.
Similarly, I’ve read that housing renovation is not
eligible to be counted toward our housing allocation
quota. But again, this turns out not to be the
case. Projects that qualify
as “substantial rehabilitation” can qualify against
ABAG housing mandates (Gov. Code 65583(c)(1)). This
kind of misinformation can discourage private capital
from investing in something we actually need and can
do.
Bottom line: I think the information being given to
the public is grossly inadequate. In fact, getting to
the truth is a full-time undertaking. ABAG has made it
clear they have no intention of answering our
questions (see Mill Valley Patch, 03-28-12,
“Housing Debate Heats Up”). Planning “workshops” and
“community input” sessions for
Plan Bay Area are so tightly orchestrated that
meaningful dialog is completely eliminated. And even
at the local level, I’ve seen our hard working
Planning Commissioners ask staff for clarifications
about the myriad of inter-related affordable housing
regulations only to get explanations that are so
simplistic, so “inside the box” that they only support
the top-down point of view.
All this considered, I wonder sometimes if the fox
isn’t guarding the hen house, or if governing has
gotten so complicated that our planning officials are
just in way over their heads. Either way, who is
looking out for the community’s interests? In the
meantime the only ones who’ve benefited from these
one-sided interpretations of the law are ABAG and
developers promoting new construction projects that
are mostly market rate (i.e. highly profitable)
housing.
I want to make it clear that I have nothing against
profits, and there are some very good nonprofit
organizations that have been building and managing
affordable housing projects in Marin for decades. Many
of these address real demand, like housing for the
elderly and Section 8 tenants. I hope they’re making a
profit so they can continue to do what they do. But
the widely embraced “market rate
+ in-lieu units” approach promoted by the ABAG quota
system (which is primarily profit driven) has
more downside than upside
for the community and it’s not going to get us where
we need to go.
As it stands, by dutifully following mandates from
above we’re giving away the store and getting next to
nothing in return.
A Cycle of
Failure
Our affordable housing challenges go much further
than just getting housing built. In fact, that’s the
easy part. In Part I, I talked about the demise of
Pruitt Igoe, as an
example of a failed affordable
housing concept. And there’s no question that
segregating the poor in isolated
housing developments remains a really bad idea.
But
Pruitt Igoe failed for many other reasons, the
most important of which was the lack of ongoing
funding for maintenance, management, replacement of
fixtures, appliances and equipment, and proper
security.
It’s easy to put up a trophy project (which
Pruitt Igoe was in its day) funded by high
profile, one-time grants and zoning concessions. It’s
easy to have a big party where self-congratulating
politicians and housing advocates show up for photo
ops of shovels being put into the ground. But it’s a
whole other thing to keep that enterprise going for
the long term. It’s a whole other thing to maintain
the buildings year after year, and to work with
families and individuals who live on the edge, day to
day.
The truth is that Priutt Igoe was abandoned by its
creators and left to fend for itself as the fickle
winds of politics shifted to other vote-grabbing
issues, long before it was abandoned by its tenants.
We’re seeing this same story unfold in Marin. A
big fuss is made about the grants that help affordable
projects like the Fireside in Mill Valley get
built. But where will the revenues come from to keep
projects like this operating and well maintained in 10
years? While housing advocates cheer on every new
project proposed, regardless of its merits, the steady
deterioration of our existing affordable housing stock
continues to be a chronic problem. And many existing
Section 8 projects around the county continue
to have disproportionately
higher crime rates and other ongoing management
and maintenance issues that give affordable housing
its bad reputation. These projects continue to need
more operating funds. But where is the effort to
address that need and why aren’t we addressing that
first?
Going forward, who will bear the social and economic
burdens of the future projects driven by
SB375 and the One Bay
Area plan? And just how financially
“sustainable” will the Sustainable Communities
Strategy really be?
As a former affordable housing developer and owner of
large Section 8 housing projects, I can say
unequivocally that these types of projects are much
more management and capital intensive than any other
type of real estate. And when we look at the other
types of affordable housing Marin communities
really need or the demographic we should really be
concentrating on (low and very low income residents),
I don’t see the sources of adequate future revenues to
ensure success. But no one seems to be thinking about
that right now. Affordable housing is just discussed
academically, as if the world were really that simple.
Right now, it’s just “build baby build.”
But wouldn’t it make more sense to work together
locally and regionally to pressure the federal
government to offer better
financing terms to qualified buyers (i.e. 40
year amortized mortgages) so more families could buy
homes? Wouldn’t it make more sense to fight for more
types of financial assistance to
low-income renters and landlords so renters
could afford a better place to live and private
property owners had more financial wherewithal to
renovate and build rental housing than to
waste precious time and money
trying to
re-engineer human behavior and warehouse people in high density
“workforce” housing next to highways?
Making
Better Decisions
One thing I’m sure of is that we’re not going to
solve today’s planning and affordable housing
challenges by continuing to rehash old ideas. More
“business as usual” will just add to our long term
problems. Equally, we’re not going to move forward by
going backwards, dismantling decades of environmental
protections in the name of “streamlining" and “jobs”
and “growth.”
"Environmental" laws like SB375 that pretend to
be one thing but are driven by something else (Appendix
A) are leading to a chain reaction of bad ideas.
For example, the scope of the new “Preferred
Land Use and Transportation Scenario” just
published by the
TAM Executive Committee includes examining “CEQA streamlining opportunities
for development projects as defined by SB375.”
Am I the only one whose head spins from the irony of
all this? Yes, there may be instances of abuses of
environmental protection laws, but name one area of
the law where that’s not true. It’s no justification
for removing protections or not having a thorough
public process.
Things today tend to get reduced to pointless "for" or
"against" arguments. But when it comes to affordable
housing, we need to be asking more substantive
questions about exactly how, where, what kind, why,
when, by what means, to whose benefit and what are the
unexplored alternatives. We need to move the
conversation from the general to the specific. And the
only way to do that is locally. This is the
fundamental purpose of public policy.
Well-crafted
local public policy has to lead our
vision of the future, not consultant’s opinions, not
academic studies, not housing quotas, not a
developer’s bottom line, not special interest groups,
and not a billionaire philanthropist’s pet project.
That’s letting the tail wag the dog and only leads to
knee-jerk decisions and more wasting of public assets,
not lasting solutions.
The kind of process we’re witnessing that
substitutes orchestrated group
workshops and consultant’s studies for
thinking is a recipe
for disaster. I don’t question for a minute the
heartfelt concern and passion of affordable housing
advocates for wanting to correct our world’s social
inequities. But I do question their understanding of
economics and their acumen about the political
horse-trading that’s going on in Sacramento, at
our expense.
But make no mistake about it, the planning challenges
we’re facing today are unlike anything we’ve dealt
with in the past. The world is faster and more
interdependent. Our problems are more complex and our
errors will be more costly. Our environmental
challenges are more precarious than ever before and
many affordable housing development sites that have
traditionally been considered (e.g. sites at or below
sea level) are no longer really viable. We’ve learned
so much about environmental sustainability and human
health in the past 20 years, and the outcry from the
scientific community is so loud and clear, that we can
no longer simplistically equate “building” with
“progress,” or make decisions just for the sake of
short-term economic growth. And we can no longer
justify putting low income or
elderly residents in harm’s way and call it a
solution.
Looking Ahead
We find ourselves in uncharted waters. The
undeniable trend at the state level is the systematic
dismantling of local control. Regional Housing
Needs Assessments, which began decades ago as a
fairly benign way of estimating growth in
California to assist cities in planning for it,
have become a heavy handed, well-funded, quota-driven
system that attempts to wrest
control of local planning
by forcing zoning changes to accommodate high density,
multi-family development (as a condition for
certification of a Housing Element).
I believe this entire system needs to be questioned to
its core.
I remain convinced that the best
affordable housing solutions will come from the
local level, guided by local
policy, informed by local
conditions, needs and markets. There may be
commonalities among the affordable housing solutions
devised by different Bay Area communities and
if so, that’s great. But there certainly aren’t any
solutions that can be applied in all cases, because
Marin, thank goodness, is just too nuanced for
that to work.
As we look ahead toward more equitable housing
solutions, in the words of Apple Computer’s marketing
campaign, I believe we need to “think different.”
The Best Laid Plans - Part IV: Public Policy,
Community Voice & Social Equity
“Toto, I don’t think we’re in Kansas
anymore.” ~The Wizard of
Oz
Since the market crash of 2008, real estate
developers, financiers and politicians have been
in panic mode. Though it’s clear that the debt
fueled hyper-growth of the past decades is gone
forever, they remain in deep denial. Like some
neurotic gambler who's lost it all but who’s still
hitting the tables believing he can get it all
back, these powerful interests continue to roll
the dice, regardless of the social and community
costs (quality of life, infrastructure, traffic,
schools, etc.), regardless of the environmental
costs, and regardless of the destabilizing
economic impacts in the long run. The tragedy is
how much damage could be done trying to bring back
the “good old days.”
The concentration of wealth and power at the top
and the influences of special interests are
distorting local planning priorities. As I’ve
tried to illuminate in this series, we can’t
continue to pursue top down central planning
practices or social engineering experiments that
have repeatedly failed in the past. And since “the
market” has not solved all our problems as
promised, and left too many needs unmet, what
should we be doing?
I have no intention of wrapping this all up with a
simplistic “to do” list. I only hope these
articles act as a catalyst for more productive
dialog. Solutions can only start in each
community, each in their own way. But one thing
that is clear is if we want to bring about
effective change, our city and county officials
are going to have to step outside their historical
comfort zones of only looking at issues that are
strictly local. We can no longer divorce ourselves
from the big picture because it’s what is
increasingly driving everything.
It’s true that most city council members are
unpaid volunteers and legitimately complain about
having too big a workload as it is. So it’s hard
enough to get them to cooperate on Marin’s shared
concerns much less problems that have state,
national or international implications. But then
again, planning staff is generally very well paid
and could be doing much more. Isolationism has
worked in the past but we just don’t live in that
world anymore. |
Black Monday; The Crash of
1929 - Library of Congress |
What Is the Problem We’re Trying to Solve?
Marin’s
fundamental disconnect with the ABAG / MTC /
One Bay Area / New Urbanism approach is that
the planning challenges in Marin today are in
many ways the opposite of what the One Bay
Area approach was created to address.
As I’ve said in Part I,
we already have much of what it promises in
terms of sustainability and quality of life.
And Marin’s affordable housing needs are quite
different from most of the other ABAG
communities.
In more urban parts of the Bay Area
(San Francisco, Oakland, Emeryville, San Jose,
etc.) market rate, single family residential
homes are more difficult to build profitably
and average household incomes are lower, but
there are more opportunities to find high
density housing sites. So in those cities it
makes some sense to promote market rate and 80
percent median income housing development in
addition to affordable units.
But in Marin the only thing developers
want to build is single family detached market
rate housing or high end condos so we
shouldn’t have to deal with quotas for that
(or “quotas” at all for that matter). Our
problem is that there is
little we can do to incentivize developers to
build low and very low income housing
and the other types of housing we really need
(see
Part III). Marin’s challenges are
about more than just the size or distribution
of
Regional Housing Needs Allocation (RNHA )
numbers. |
Marin County Housing Needs Allocation, 2007 to
2014
|
Very Low, <50% |
Low, <80% |
Moderate, <120% |
Above Moderate |
Total |
Belevedere |
5 |
4 |
4 |
4 |
17 |
Corte Madera |
66 |
38 |
46 |
92 |
244 |
Fairfax |
23 |
12 |
19 |
54 |
108 |
Larkspur |
90 |
55 |
75 |
162 |
382 |
Mill Valley |
74 |
54 |
68 |
96 |
292 |
Novato |
275 |
171 |
221 |
574 |
1,241 |
Ross |
8 |
6 |
5 |
8 |
27 |
San Anselmo |
26 |
19 |
21 |
47 |
113 |
San Rafael |
262 |
207 |
288 |
646 |
1,403 |
Sausalito |
45 |
30 |
34 |
56 |
165 |
Tiburon |
36 |
21 |
27 |
33 |
117 |
Unincorporated |
183 |
137 |
169 |
284 |
773 |
Marin Total |
1,095 |
754 |
977 |
2,056 |
4,882 |
|
Housing Elements and Land Entitlement
When Marin cities draft their
Housing Elements, they typically include a
list of designated sites
for rezoning for affordable housing. In
the past this has been a relatively benign
exercise and generally considered an “unfunded
mandate.” But that has changed.
Creating a specific list
of sites has actually never been a good idea.
It arbitrarily skews property valuations and
essentially gives entitlement advantages to one
property owner over another for no good reason
other than one site might be vacant land. It’s
inequitable and offers no incentive for property
owners who are not on the list to step up and
propose affordable housing or mixed use
projects. These are some of the reasons why a
method led by public policy would be better for
all (Appendix
B). However, even with that aside, in our
new regulatory climate the creation of a fixed
“list of sites” is now more problematic than
before.
Senate Bill
375 has created a link between zoning
and the Housing Element sites list. It adds
language that creates a legal gray area that
could allow a private developer to force a
zoning change if their proposed project
qualifies by having
at least 49 percent
affordable units. Now the newly proposed
SB226
would remove CEQA protections for
“infill” development (a vaguely defined term)
and the Transportation Authority of Marin's
(TAM) recent “Preferred
Land Use and Transportation Scenario”
proposes that transit-
oriented development sites be entirely exempt
from CEQA (California Environmental
Quality Act) review. Finally, the proposed
SB1220 contemplates a state controlled
fund to finance these kinds of projects.
In combination, these laws effectively
strip away our Conditional
Use and Planned Development (PD) zoning approval
protections and eliminate CEQA Environmental
Impact Reports, leaving only our Design
Review process, which is not adequate and in
many cases would no longer be a legal method to
stop projects we don't want.
This legal nexus between the Housing Element
(part of the General Plan) and
SB375 essentially means that putting a
site on a list has now become a significant step
toward land rights entitlement (financial value)
that developers can
rely upon and sue
to protect even though they may not yet own the
property (it can be under option to purchase)
and the city has not yet rezoned it.
We should not underestimate the formidable
changes these regulations could bring about once
there is sufficient funding to aggressively
enforce them.
Affordable Housing Demand
There is no question that affordable options
in Marin are scarcer than in some other
parts of the region. But the existence of
high-priced suburban communities like those
found in Marin is true in every metropolitan
area in the country. It’s the price we pay
for a free society. So this fact of life in
and of itself is neither discriminatory nor
justification for running roughshod over local
zoning control.
In addition, often quoted statistics about how
many people work in Marin and live elsewhere are
not the same as proof of “market demand” for
housing. If that were the case, the Fireside
Project in Mill Valley would have
filled up in 10
minutes instead of 2 years
and the Millworks project in Novato
would not have resulted in
huge financial losses. I wonder how much
more “progress” our communities will have to
endure before housing advocates accept this
truth.
These projects founder because they ignore how
markets work. Housing construction cannot
logically precede economic growth or jobs growth
because the quality of that growth and the
kinds of jobs created
determine what kinds of housing is needed,
not vice versa.
The only real evidence we have of affordable
housing demand remains the
County’s Section 8 waiting
list (something we should be
addressing much more effectively). Other
arguments about housing our police officers,
firefighters and government workers ring
hollow. Today, government workers on average
make more than comparable private sector
employees (salary, benefits, retirement and
health care). And just ask a firefighter
or policeman about where he or she lives.
Our “workforce” clearly understands the
difference between what they will do to get a
job and where they want to live with their
families (Appendix
A). Given
the choice of living in a cramped apartment
“project” or driving an hour and renting (or
owning) a bigger place with a yard, it’s no
contest what they will choose every
time.
So who exactly are we trying to help?
Social Engineering at Its Worst
Last week I had the opportunity to sit in on
a Town Council meeting in Corte Madera where
Mark Luce, president of ABAG, made a
presentation defending the value of being an
ABAG member city. His boilerplate
presentation was unsurprising in that it had
only good things to say about the organization
and its goals. His “facts” were typically
one-sided and his conclusions about the
greenhouse gas emissions
consequences of
SB375 were academic and
inaccurate
(Appendix A). But what was most striking was
when he began to espouse the virtues of
social engineering.
Mr. Luce made it clear he believes that it’s
socially equitable to provide high density housing next to
freeways for our low income
“workforce.” But he went on to say that this
kind of housing was good for “these people”
because if they worked near their apartment (I
assume in a low paying service job) they would
"spend more time with their children,” inferring
that they would therefore be better parents.
Astonishingly, he felt ABAG somehow had the
moral authority to pass this kind of judgment on
other people’s parenting. But what was even more
amazing was how surprised and clueless he was
when people on the council and in the audience
reacted in shock to his over-reaching and
high-handed remarks. He finally admitted that
this was perhaps only his opinion but he seemed
to have no qualms about enforcing it on others,
even though he holds no elected office with the
powers to do so (nor does anyone else,
thankfully).
I’m sure Mr. Luce would be the first one to be
aghast if I told him that he had to move his
family from the comfort of their bucolic Napa
Valley home to live in Corte Madera next to a
highway on-ramp. Yet he saw no incongruity at
all in his ringing endorsement of “engineering”
that outcome for “our workforce.”
Workforce
Housing
Well-intended housing advocates (who are
unwittingly carrying water for development
interests in Sacramento) often try to
characterize local resistance to affordable
housing as a “civil rights” issue or the result
of “racism” (in addition to the NIMBY argument –
see Part
III). But it seems to me that it’s the
RHNA quota system,
dutifully enforced by subservient ABAG
planners, that is promulgating racist or
certainly “class-ist” thinking about the needs
of “those people” who will live in their beloved
high density projects.
In fact I think the entire concept of “workforce
housing” is elitist. “Our workforce” is
discussed as if working people are second class
citizens who don’t need yards for their children
to play in, fresh air to breathe, views of
something other than a concrete off-ramp, or God
forbid to be paid a living wage in the first
place. Well, this may come as news to those who
sit in high positions at ABAG, MTC, BCDC and
BAAQMD, Sacramento politicians, and affordable
housing advocates, but “those people” who live
in low income housing have the same hopes and
dreams for their family and their children’s
future that you do. They only live there because
they have no other choice. They are not “our
workforce." They are our fellow citizens,
entitled to want the same things we enjoy,
regardless of their financial status, education,
ethnicity or lack of luck in life.
We’re often told that too many workers have to
come from Richmond to
work in Marin and that this is
the reason we need to invest in more affordable
housing. But the more obvious question is
why aren’t we, as a
society, investing in
education, jobs and community development in
Richmond so people can find high paying
work there and have a safe community to live in?
Then maybe people in Marin would have to start
paying their imported housekeepers, nannies and
gardeners a decent living wage and benefits to
compete.
Sometimes I wonder whose lifestyle we’re really
trying to improve.
But then, even when we do offer low income
residents a chance to buy a home here, we deny
them the only real value of home ownership:
equity appreciation. We cap their upside for 30
or 40 years and deny them the fruits of sweat
equity. This is nothing more than a modern
version of indentured servitude.
I think the whole thing is absolutely shameful.
The “Market”
What affordable housing advocates forget is
that it wasn’t the massive projects the
government built (see Part I) that ultimately
solved the housing shortages of the late 1940’s
and 1950’s. Like it or not, it was the much
maligned, privately financed developments
like Levittown, incentivized by the G.I. Bill
and federally insured mortgages, that filled the
need.
That said, I’m not suggesting that markets will
solve all our problems or that we should build
more Levittowns, quite the opposite. Without
government support at all levels, the market
will remain incapable of providing housing for
those most in need (low and very low income
residents). But what I am suggesting is that
private investment
backed by strong policy incentives can help
provide a great deal of the kinds of housing we
really need. The blunt instrument of massive
quasi-government agencies getting involved
in local zoning and planning won’t. The One
Bay Area Plan approach attempts to micro-
manage everything to death (Appendix
C).
We can’t afford to keep sending tax money up to
the federal and state level only to have it come
back in the form of policies that remove
control over local decision making and work
against our community planning interests.
Likewise, waiting for change to come from the
top is pointless. So where does that leave us?
Show Me the Money
Everywhere we look today we’re told there’s
no money to pay for anything we need.
"Austerity" is the big buzzword. And discussions
about the role of government have distilled down
to “less government” versus “more government.”
This makes long term planning more difficult.
But the problem is not whether we need more
government or less government. It’s about how to
get “better” government and more efficient and
productive government for “less” cost. And in
the process we have to create more “value” from
what we do.
Our national public policy and financial
challenges are far too numerous and complex to
address in this article. However, there are
things we need to understand to make better
decisions locally.
The historic lows in interest rates being paid
by the U.S. government have a lesson to teach
us. At a time when we are “lending” our
government money in unprecedented amounts for a
negative return (inflation adjusted), the market
is telling us that it’s not a lack of money
that’s the problem. It’s the lack of confidence
that anything is worth taking the risk to invest
in. We need to think about how to break that
logjam.
Under the circumstances, I would suggest that
it’s the federal government’s responsibility to
“invest” that money back into the country, and
local government’s responsibility to make our
needs known to them. It may seem
counter-intuitive but when money is almost free
and everyone is paralyzed by fear, it’s a good
time to borrow and invest for the long term.
But in our post “debt bubble” world our money
must be spent more wisely.
Nuts and Bolts and Finance
I think the “bailout” of General Motors
has been tarred unfairly. I think it was a smart
move. With GM, rather than being the “banker” of
last resort, the U.S. Treasury acted as the
“investment banker” of last resort and the
result so far has been profitable for U.S.
taxpayers. The funds GM received were not a gift
but an investment in return for an equity stake.
Could this be a way to finance planning and
housing initiatives?
Grants, bonds and tax incentives will
undoubtedly continue to play an important role
in affordable housing finance and housing
markets in general. And I would argue for the need to expand Section 8
subsidies with new types of vouchers that offer
more local control
over how they are used. But providing
local,
state and federal government-backed financing,
debt insurance and even equity participation to
the mix may be the better way to move ahead than
traditional government “hand-outs.” New
types of public / private partnerships could
also increase financial leverage and provide a
backstop for innovative local solutions.
For example, Napa County has a small
equity-sharing program that offers interest free
funds that buyers can use toward their down
payment when they purchase a home. Repayment is
due on sale. It helps people who otherwise
couldn’t qualify. This kind of incentive could
also be accomplished by insuring mortgage debt
in exchange for equity. And programs like these
scale up well from humble beginnings.
It may take years for housing markets to fully
recover and we may see flat home prices with
little inflation adjusted appreciation for a
decade, but it’s time to plan for the future.
Affordable Housing and Social Equity
There was a saying in the 1960’s: “If you’re
not part of the solution, you’re part of the
problem.” The updated version of that should be:
“If you don’t see that it’s all connected, you
don't understand the problem.” Social equity is
a complex challenge.
Ensuring a quality education, including college,
for everyone who’s willing to work hard to earn
it is essential for our society’s long term
success. But saddling the next generation with
$100,000 in debt before they even get their
first job is no way to promote household
formation or social equity. And where will the
jobs come from unless we
support the kinds of industries we'll need to
live in a sustainable world? Local zoning and
planning can play a special role here, nurturing
new, sustainable businesses like green
technology development and medical research.
We know that investing in our health pays back
many times over in increased productivity, lower
medical costs, and greater happiness. And happy,
productive people have families, buy homes and
strengthen communities. But today almost 20
percent of our population has no healthcare
coverage and even people with health insurance
are just one major illness away from bankruptcy.
And with hunger becoming a widespread problem,
how can we expect anyone to escape poverty if
they have to worry about getting enough to eat
every day? Yet local stores and restaurants
throw out enough food every week to feed
thousands.
Finally, issues like Marin County pension reform
and social equity are related simply because our
financial resources have limits. Yet we have our
county supervisors dolling out taxpayer-funded
“discretionary grants” to questionable pet
projects, while allowing vital health services
like the County Public Health Lab in San Rafael
to risk closure. The annual expenditures of our
county supervisor’s personal slush funds (which
are unique in all of California) greatly exceed
the cost of running the San Rafael lab. Yet not
a single supervisor has offered to give back
those funds to save it.
Social equity is also about getting our
priorities straight.
Public Transportation and Growth
We hear a lot of talk from ABAG and MTC about
public transportation and building
high density housing near
“quality” transportation corridors (an
oxymoron in Marin,
if there ever was one). But here's my question:
how did we get to this place where everything is
backwards?
Historically, public transportation was built to
serve economic growth and population demand, not
to create it. Railroads connected distant
regions to facilitate commerce. Subways and
trolleys allowed people to get around more
efficiently in crowded cities. But now we have
transportation planners dictating where growth
is “supposed to” happen and how we should
engineer it.
Thankfully, our cities are already very “walkable,”
but it’s true that Marin’s population would be
better served by more public transportation
options. As it stands, Marin has no
significant public transportation other than bus
routes. With the topography, street
configurations and geographical distances
between cities in Marin being what they
are, other kinds of public transportation that
work in urban areas (subways,
light rail, etc.)
just won’t work here. And any public
transportation
system that’s going to work in Marin is
going to have to be extremely
flexible, adaptive and
non-polluting. Still, there are
possibilities.
For example, one solution might be a fleet of
relatively inexpensive (as opposed to SMART
trains) electrically
powered shuttle
buses monitored and managed in
real time by a wireless “demand” sensing system
(21st century street cars). Each shuttle would
travel on a “flexible” route that can adapt to
rider demand. Riders with registered accounts or
pre- paid trip cards can “tell” the system that
they need a pickup at a shuttle stop by
inserting their card in a reader or notifying
the system via a smartphone app. The shuttle bus
routes and stop locations are predetermined but
shuttle drivers know beforehand whether or not
there are riders there in need of pickups. So
the system offers feedback to adapt the diver’s
route to operate at maximum efficiency. The
route configurations can also “learn” from
experience and adapt to changes in user demand,
over time.
Or perhaps we could be promoting car-sharing
(like Zipcars, but using only hybrid or electric
vehicles) to alleviate traffic congestion and
promote a healthy environment. The point is
there are many things we can do locally that are
relatively inexpensive (and possibly even
profitable) and can be implemented quickly. We
need to consider all our public transportation
options rather than confine ourselves to the
traditional thinking proposed by ABAG, MTC and
TAM.
Local Voices Equal Better Solutions
Marin’s unique housing and planning
challenges are a strong argument for a Marin
Council of Governments (COG). Corte Madera
has proposed that a Marin COG or a North Bay COG
that includes Marin, Napa and Sonoma, would have
many advantages. For one thing a Marin COG would
allow us to develop our own criteria for our
Sustainable Communities Strategy (SCS) and our
Housing Needs Analysis. These would be based on
our own job and population growth projections
and our unique community assets, not a generic
formula foisted on us by Sacramento. Working
together, we would have the critical mass to
deal with the state directly regarding our
Regional Housing Need Assessment allocations (RHNA)
and more effectively argue for the types of
housing we really need (See Part III).
The “party line” response to this idea is that a
Marin COG is bad because we’d just end up
fighting amongst ourselves, city against city,
about how to divide up our RHNA allocations
instead of fighting with ABAG. Wow, talk about
cynicism! With that attitude and that complete
lack of faith in the judgment, intelligence,
creativity and motivations of our neighboring
cities, no wonder there’s so little cooperation
or innovation at the top. Seeing challenges like
this as opportunities instead of obstacles is
called “leadership.” It’s the fundamental
ability required to be an effective public
servant. And I think anyone who espouses this
simple-minded objection has given up on
democracy and should be voted out of office.
But there is another reason to have a seat at
the table in Sacramento via our own COG. It
involves our ability to lobby for or against
some of the regulations that are headed our way.
Having a Marin COG that promotes an agenda that
serves our communities, rather than development
and financial special interests, could be an
important step toward shaping how new laws like
SB375, and potentially SB226
and
SB1220, are administered.
A Marin COG could support the kinds of solutions
that are best adapted to our local needs.
Leadership and New Directions
So where will leadership come from? In
addition to forming a Marin or North Bay COG, I
think the Marin County Council of Mayors and
Council members is a good place to start. This
sleepy organization could quickly reinvent
itself as a force for collaboration and change.
They already have the platform to hold
countywide forums on major issues, do countywide
assessments of public opinion, and study
alternatives. They only need to act.
Another interesting approach would be the
creation of a hybrid nonprofit / for profit
“venture philanthropy fund” that focuses on
financing local planning and affordable housing
initiatives.
As it is now, on one side we have traditional
stand-alone nonprofit foundations that often
have agendas that are not necessarily aligned
with the goals of all Marin cities. And on the
other side we have for profit investors and
nonprofit housing developers that find it hard
to make the numbers work to build the kinds of
projects Marin really needs or to incorporate
our big picture planning goals into their plans.
In the middle are Marin cities that lack funding
for full time staff dedicated to project
finance. So housing and planning decisions end
up being made through a mish-mash of competing
financial interests or available grants, which
rarely result in positive community outcomes.
A hybrid venture philanthropy fund might
offer a way to help facilitate better solutions
and have advantages over traditional
philanthropy or housing trusts. It can
potentially attract more money because it can
work on countywide initiatives that have a
larger scope and a longer time horizon, and it
can source funds from both donors and investors.
With a hybrid fund, for profit corporations and
individual investors collaborate side by side
with foundations, individual donors, donor
advised funds, non-governmental organizations
(NGOs) and local and state government, with each
receiving the kinds of investment returns or
public benefit outcomes they require. This
financing model is being used successfully at
the nonprofit organization I currently manage
and extensively by others for medical research
and technology development.
With a hybrid entity, every type of financing
option is available and investment sources need
not be local. For profit investors can retain
equity, provide loans, participate in revenues,
and use return enhancing financial leverage.
Nonprofit participants can provide grants, low
cost loans, loan guarantees, and participate in
financial upside through the use of program
related investments. And local governments can
participate through the issuance of bonds or
participation certificates. All these methods
can be brought together a single initiative or
spread across a wide variety of projects.
A venture philanthropy fund could also work
closely with a Marin COG to analyze and
finance planning and housing solutions. And its
involvement could include promoting Marin’s
funding opportunities to the national investment
/ donor community, and Marin’s financial
interests in Sacramento. This kind of hybrid
funding approach might be particularly
applicable for financing privately owned infill,
second unit, building conversion, renovation,
and mixed use development. The kind of
development that is scattered and not built by
major developers but is most suited to our
"built out" Marin cities.
A complete discussion of this is beyond the
scope of this article. But it’s an intriguing
idea.
Working Collaboratively
I want to thank all those throughout Marin,
in and out of government, who have stepped up
and spoken out for local control in spite of
considerable pressure and criticism. And I want
to thank all the long-time community activists
who’ve fought lonely battles for decades to
preserve our environment and demand better
government.
I want to thank Linda Pfeifer of Sausalito,
Jeanne Macleamy and Denise Athas of Novato, and
Larry Chu of Larkspur for asking hard questions.
And special thanks to Bob Ravasio, Diane Furst,
Carla Condon and the entire Corte Madera town
council for leading the effort to form a Marin
Council of Governments. And thanks also to some
of our county supervisors, who have finally
started questioning ABAG’s job and population
growth projections that form the basis of the
RHNA housing allocations.
But far too many people still continue to live
in their own little worlds, falling back on the
excuse that they are just too “busy” to get
involved. But if you don’t participate, if you
don’t make your voice heard, you will get what
you deserve. However, what worries me is that if
you don't speak up, I may also get what you
deserve. So please join in. Those leading the
call for new approaches and greater government
transparency need your support. So write
letters, send emails, attend meetings, meet with
your representatives and make some noise so
you’ll be heard over the relentless din of
special interests.
If we want sustainable solutions, that’s where
it all starts. And Marin cities need to work
together on housing, planning and social equity
challenges, while change is still possible. This
is an instance where self-interest and common
interest are one in the same. We need to get
ABAG and Sacramento to understand that the
unique characteristics of our communities are
our strengths that can inform unique
locally-driven solutions rather than obstacles
to their simple-minded goals from the top.
Hard Truths
At the beginning of these articles I talked
about company towns, like Pullman, Illinois. We
look back at those times as a gilded age of
robber barons and hard times. But the sad truth
is that what we do today in terms of helping low
income workers doesn’t come close to measuring
up.
Employment at Pullman was a sought after and
prestigious position. The single family homes
offered to employees were a big step up from
what the average family lived in at the time,
and it came with family health care, clean
streets, good schools and a safe neighborhood.
Henry Ford offered his workers the highest
average pay of any company in the country so
they could afford to buy his cars, without
concern that his stock would lose half its value
or he’d lose his year-end bonus.
Today, corporations sell us planned
obsolescence, bankroll protective legislation
and bankrupt themselves to avoid pension
obligations, while worker pay and benefits
plummet. Meanwhile, young billionaire CEOs and
hedge fund traders congratulate themselves on
their brilliance, forgetting the century of hard
work that laid down the infrastructure of the
society that made their insignificant moment in
the sun possible.
Historically, we’ve always defined “solutions”
in terms of economic solutions. But as we
approach the limits to our growth (at least
under our current methods), our attention will
need to turn to other qualifiers like the
environment and quality of life. It’s a
conversation we’ve never really had to have
before.
It would be a mistake to characterize our
challenges as a simple Republicans versus
Democrats or liberal versus conservative story.
It’s much more than that. Our predicament is the
result of an unchecked public and private sector
that’s been steadily falling deeper and deeper
into debt for decades. It’s about waging wars we
can’t afford and accumulating mountains of
fanciful “stuff” on credit that we can’t afford
to pay off. It’s about inefficiencies everywhere
we look and shoveling money into “wasting
assets” instead of making long term investments.
And as a result, we find ourselves unable to do
the things we really need to do. But that
doesn’t diminish our need to do them.
Today we find ourselves besieged from all sides
by special interests trying to deconstruct
decades of environmental protections and much
needed social safety net programs. And it’s all
in the name of “jobs” or “processing efficiency”
or “boosting the economy” or some other short
term fix. But it’s just more of the same thing
that got us where we are and it won’t work.
I wonder why it’s so hard for us to do the right
thing for the long run. Is shortsightedness
programmed into our hunter-gatherer brains? Yes,
providing affordable housing opportunities and
achieving more social equity will probably mean
higher progressive taxes. But few remember that
in the 1950’s, the decade that built the
backbone of our economy, marginal tax rates on
high earners approached 90 percent. So if you
make a lot of money and you have to pay higher
taxes, why not just be grateful that your
parents and grandparents did the heavy lifting
that made it easier for you to become as wealthy
as you are?
Social equity and sustainable solutions will
require sacrifices. I think it will be worth it.
The Best Laid Plans Planning and
Affordable Housing in Marin 2012
APPENDICES
The Best Laid Plans – Appendix A
The Truth about
SB375 and the One Bay Area Plan
The stated goal of Senate Bill 375, which was
signed into law in 2008, is “to reduce greenhouse gas
emissions (GHGs)
15 percent by 2035.”
Its premise is that
building high density development with an
affordable component, close to public
transportation, will decrease GHGs and
thereby have a positive effect on
global warming.
The rationale is as follows: Section 1(a) of
SB375 states: “The transportation sector
contributes over 40 percent of the greenhouse
gas emissions in California. Automobiles and
light trucks alone contribute almost 30 percent.
The transportation sector is the single largest
contributor of greenhouse gases.”
This infers that SB375 will affect 40 percent of
all GHG emissions in California. I wondered if
that was true.
To implement this law there are two basic
requirements. That “prior to adopting a
Sustainable Communities Strategy (SCS), the
Metropolitan Planning Organization (MPO) shall
quantify the reduction in GHG emissions
projected to be achieved.” [Section 3 (G)]
and “...the MPO shall submit a description of
the methodology it intends to use to estimate
the GHG emissions reduced by its Sustainable
Communities Strategy.” [Section 3 (I) (i)]
So I decided to analyze SB375 on its own terms
to discover the truth about all this. What I
found is that the factual basis of SB375 is
faulty at best or a
carefully crafted
deception at worst. And that ABAG RHNA
(Regional Housing Needs Assessment) allocations
and SB375 will actually increase GHG emissions
in California.
Falsehood #1:
“The transportation sector
contributes over 40 percent of the greenhouse
gas emissions in California.”
The truth is that the “40 percent” figure is
a 2020 projected figure not a real measured
number. The actual amount is about 35 percent
(Source: CA Air Resources Board: updated Oct.
2010). It seems to me that basing a law on a
fabricated guesstimate of GHG emissions to
justify the law’s goals is a bit circular, isn’t
it?
In any case the real number, 35 percent, is
misleading because it includes emissions from
airlines, trains and
trams, buses, heavy construction equipment,
commercial trucking and hauling, shipping,
boats, ferries, etc.,
none of which are affected
by or addressed in SB375.
Falsehood #2:
“Automobiles and light trucks
alone contribute almost 30 percent.”
The truth is if you strip out the vehicles
above not affected by SB375, you’re left with 23 percent of GHGs
actually contributed by
automobiles and
light trucks. (Source: CA Air Resources
Board: updated Oct. 2010)
Falsehood #3:
“The transportation sector is the
single largest contributor of greenhouse gases.”
The truth is that according to California
EPA, energy production is
the number one GHG producer in the state
at 41 percent.
Transportation is second at 35 percent.
But even that’s not true because the California
Air Resources Board statistics err in saying
“livestock and animal
breeding” is only 3 percent, because
that’s just a measure of total GHG tonnage, not
global warming impact. Methane gas (the majority of
GHGs from livestock) is
35 times more
harmful than CO2 in its global warming impact.
So livestock and breeding actually
dwarfs energy and
transportation combined. But not
wanting to split hairs I decided to just use the
numbers we have so far.
So what are the facts?
SB375 and
RHNA allocations are based on the concept
that we all carry our fair or proportional
share. So I looked at the actual GHG
emissions data and
statistics for Marin County.
The total GHGs for Marin are 2.7 million
metric tons per year. With 23 percent of that
from cars and light trucks, that equals 621,000
metric tons of GHG per year. (Source: Bay Area
Air Quality Management District; Feb 2010
Report: Source Inventory of Bay Area Greenhouse
Gas Emissions).
But 23 percent is still misleading as it relates
to housing because many of our GHG
emissions are not affected
by SB375
or housing
regardless of where we build it.
These kinds of driving include:
- • Deliveries and pickups by car, truck and
van.
• Passenger vans and shuttles to private
businesses and public facilities.
• Workman and building contractor’s
transportation.
• Gardeners and home services.
• Utility service vehicles: water, power,
sewer.
• City Agency’s vehicles: police, fire, public
works.
• Health and safety vehicles.
This accounts for roughly
40 percent of vehicle
use in Marin. That leaves
60 percent of 23 percent
or 13.8 percent for personal travel.
That equates to 372,600 metric tons GHG
per year that might be
positively affected by SB375.
But 13.8 percent is still misleading because
Marin County has
no significant public transportation.
According to
city-data.com,
65 percent of the
personal driving in Marin is driving to work.
This is true regardless of where we locate
housing because:
- 1. We cannot discriminate in rentals or
sales of homes based on where people work or
what kind of job they have;
2. No one can predict where they will have
to go to find employment. People will go
where the job is;
3. People don't make the decisions about
where they work and where they live for the
same reasons (i.e. you go where the best job
opportunity is. You live where it's best for
your family or lifestyle).
That leaves 35 percent of 13.8 percent or
4.83 percent for other personal driving,
which equates to about 30,000 metric tons of
GHGs per year that might be positively
affected by SB375.
But 4.83 percent is still misleading because
most Marin County
driving is not
optional. These types of non-optional
driving include:
- • Driving to lessons, soccer, schools,
friends and social activities.
• Vacations, driving to the beach or
mountains, or a park, etc.
• Driving to buy large things we cannot
carry (paint, hardware, large grocery
purchases, plants, clothing, equipment,
etc.).
• People shop price not location (drive to
Costco, Target, etc.).
• People have busy lives and must do
multiple things in one trip.
• Because what you need is not nearby
(i.e. you go to the doctor you need, not
because he’s next door).
So all in all,
only about 10 percent of people, who are
not doing any of these things, might be
able to change their driving habits due to
SB375 / One Bay Area’s scheme for
high density housing near the highway.
That leaves only 10 percent of 4.83
percent, or 0.48 percent, which equates to
3,000 metric tons of GHGs per year could
possibly be saved by SB375. That annual
figure is approximately
½ or 1
percent of all of California’s annual GHG
output. These are statistically
insignificant savings (smaller
than 1 percent is considered a rounding
error)!
SB375 /
One Bay Area
Will Increase GHG Emissions
It turns out that SB375 and the One Bay
Area Plan will actually produce a dramatic
increase
in GHG emissions. Let’s do the
math.
A typical home produces about 8 tons of
GHGs per year. The One Bay Area
Preferred Scenario for Marin calls for the
construction of 8,150 new homes. That
equates to an additional 65,000 metric
tons of GHGs per year.
At a development scale of 20 units per
acre, about 400 acres of land developed
would be required for new housing. But I
chose to use 200 acres assuming that half
would be on undeveloped sites and half on
redeveloped sites.
The annual carbon sequestration value of
one acre of typical Marin undeveloped land
(grass with a few trees, not forested
land) is about 60 GHGs per year.
So if we lose 200
acres of land to development, that
equals more than 12,000 added GHGs. If we
then add the more than 65,000 tons of GHGs
from the new homes, then subtract the net
savings of (-3,000) from
SB375, we get a total added GHG per
year of 74,000 metric tons per year
(77,000 minus 3,000). (Source: EPA
greenhouse gas calculator).
But It Gets Worse
Most “affordable” units built in the
future to satisfy
RHNA allocations will be done using
inclusionary zoning.
This is true because the projects are
generally not financially feasible without
80 percent of the units being sold or
rented at expensive market rates.
Inclusionary is at best 20 percent of
total units built in a project.
Using the RHNA allocations in the latest
One Bay Area Preferred Scenario, we
would have to build about 3 times the
number of total affordable units required
to achieve the “affordable” component
quota using inclusionary development
methods. Doing this, will
increase
the total GHGs produced by
SB375 by hundreds of thousands of
additional metric tons per year.
Solutions?
The problem is that cars and light
trucks produce GHG emissions. So why not
just fix the problem instead of destroying
our communities, and creating
unsustainable growth and unwieldy
bureaucracies?
We should force
vehicle manufacturers to produce more fuel
efficient cars, trucks and
other transportation right now. How about
levying an MPG tax on every new car or
truck sold that doesn’t get at least 35
miles per gallon (the newly proposed
2016 CAFE standard)
and a tax credit for the purchase of those
that exceed it? That would penalize high
pollution vehicles but make low emission
vehicles cheaper by comparison for
consumers, and reward innovators.
SB375 & One Bay Area
SB 375/One Bay Area is without
any statistical or scientific basis. Its
“top down” housing mandates and compliance
demands are unprecedented in California
legal history, and remove significant
local control of zoning and planning.
SB375/One Bay Area is economically
destabilizing and financially
irresponsible. Housing without jobs equals
“unsustainable” development (think:
Vallejo, Modesto and Fresno). It’s
environmentally destructive. It
contradicts the fundamental the laws of
supply and demand, free markets, and how
cities grow and survive.
I believe that SB375’s legal ambiguities
and contradictions make it open to legal
challenge as to the enforceability of some
of its more onerous provisions.
What is most troubling is that in the end,
after all the costs and burdens that SB375
and One Bay Area will impose on our
communities, it will
not result in providing what we really
want: more high quality jobs
and more quality, affordable housing
choices to those most in need.
48
The Best Laid Plans – Appendix B
A Criteria-Based Approach to Housing
Policy for Mill
Valley
In September 2011, I met with City
Manager Jim McCann and discussed the
Housing Element and a new approach to
addressing ABAG / RHNA housing
allocations. It is called the "Criteria
Based" method of designating development
sites.
This approach, combined with the offering
of various financial and zoning
incentives, could have significant
advantages over the simplistic "list the
sites" approach that is presently driving
so much community antagonism and
distorting developers' understanding of
"of right" zoning.
Since the City Council is now considering
the General Plan and Housing Element, I
felt it was a good time to reintroduce
some of this information. I urge you to
make Mill Valley a leader in
affordable housing solutions by building
on the strengths of our community, rather
than seeing those strengths as obstacles
to planning.
As it is presently, we select a very
limited and superficially determined list
of affordable housing sites, which due to
real world circumstances can end up being
less suitable in the long run than they
appeared to be at first glance. The
Richardson proposal for 20 units at
Camino Alto and Blithedale
Avenue is a case in point. The Super Duper
Burger site on Miller Avenue is
another because the list makers failed to
understand the financial staying power of
the corporate land owner.
From a developer's point of view, almost
all of the properties along Miller
Avenue and in other commercial areas
throughout the city that are more than 30
years old are potentially developable
sites if the terms of purchase and
financing are favorable. But there is no
way to determine at any given moment which
ones those are just by looking at them.
The criteria-based method designates sites
with the highest potential for affordable
housing development based on a "points"
system. Development proposals with the
highest point ratings would qualify for
the most incentives and benefits.
Possible Criteria
The "Criteria" that earned points
might include that a site is:
• Economically obsolete (there is no
longer any rental demand for that type
of structure: i.e. a warehouse building
in an office / retail area).
• Functionally obsolete (the structure
is so far out of code compliance and
lacks so many amenities / features that
no good tenant will rent it)
• Underutilized (the site is far below
its build out potential - allowable
floor area ratio)
• Hazardous (a building that is somehow
a public danger due to toxic materials,
etc.) Unsafe (a structure is in danger
of collapse or damage to adjacent
structures, or is otherwise a public
safety problem). ...and that the
proposed development:
• Offers significant low and very
low income units (the type and count
would increase the points)
• Offers a type of housing unit that
is presently desired / most needed in
Mill Valley (live/work lofts,
"starter" studio units, elderly units,
etc. - contrary to perception the
majority of our population is single
household, single parents, elderly and
renters)
• Includes a list of desirable "green"
building techniques and materials.
• Includes a list of desirable
technology and safety innovations.
• Provides a desirable public amenity
(a path or lane, a public space, a
shelter, parking, etc.) Improves
public access and safety (pedestrian,
vehicular, etc.)
These are just some possible
criteria. The list needs input from
all sides. The actual allocation of
financial and zoning incentives /
benefits would not be administrative
but subject to the normal public
hearing process at the Planning
Commission and City Council.
Advantages
A criteria based method creates a
stated public policy objective that
developers can respond to with more
certainty and creativity than a "list
of designated sites" approach. This
would save developers a considerable
amount of uncertainty, which is
presently one of the major causes of
animosity and processing difficulties.
1. This method is responsive to
dynamic and unpredictable economy and
market forces, whereas a "static list"
is not.
2. Under the existing "list of sites"
method problems of fairness and public
equity arise if a developer wants to
develop a site not on the list but
which is actually, based on market
conditions, more easily and profitably
developed.
3. We can clearly demonstrate to ABAG
how this criteria based system
combined with properly aligned
application processing and financial
incentives (tax and fee deferments /
amortization, etc.) satisfies the RHNA
numbers many times over.
4. This method maximizes the number of
potential sites, maximizes the
potential number of housing units that
can be added citywide, and allows
market forces and
community voices to work together to
achieve our goals.
5. Because this method increases the
number of potential sites, it
alleviates the pressure for
unrealistic density.
6. The
criteria based approach could also be
applied to second units and
multifamily renovations - i.e. if a
rehab was "significant" in that it met
enough criteria to earn enough points
and/or involved enough
change/upgrades, it could earn
possible incentives. There might even
be different criteria lists
(variations) designed for each type of
situation - i.e. new construction,
renovation and second units.
Other Considerations
Adopting a criteria-based approach
should be in conjunction with the
legitimate push back on ABAG
classifying Mill Valley as
"urban," which should be changed to
"Suburban" to allow 20 units per acre
maximum and not 30 units.
Densities greater than 20 per acre are
not feasible even with the kinds of
unsustainable bonuses we've been
giving away. For instance, 505 Miller
Avenue (Hawk’s Tavern, etc.) at 20 per
acre is very dense and 3 stories high,
and required a variance for 22 off
site/on the street parking spaces in
the public parking to do even that.
I think this method should be adopted
in conjunction with zoning code
changes that the public has strongly
endorsed over the past 10 years, such
as that Miller Avenue should be
limited to a maximum of two stories of
construction. Please note that this
suggestion is backed up by the
"Alternative Analysis" (Appendix
D for link) that I presented to
the city in 2007. That study shows
that we already have sufficient
developable sites and can achieve ABAG/RHNA
numbers by building two-story
structures.
The Best Laid Plans – Appendix C
Why
“One Bay Area’s”
Growth
Plan is Not the Solution for
Marin –
Part I
The following is the
text of a letter sent to the Mill
Valley City Council in January
2012, but its principles apply to all
California cities. 3/1/12
Dear Elected Officials:
I encourage you to please read Dick
Spotswood's latest piece on the
Association of Bay Area Governments'
(ABAG) One Bay Area Plan. As he
shows with great clarity, the growth
assumptions of the plan are without
any basis in facts.
To this, I would like to also add
these facts:
• The number one
greenhouse gas emitter in the U.S.
and California is "energy
production." In fact the Richmond
refinery is the number one polluter
in the state. That is followed in
order by businesses and industry,
agriculture, public and commercial
transportation and then residential
/ local driving at the very bottom
of the list. So this entire plan is
focused on the least important
contributor to greenhouse gas
emissions.
• No
development plan can guarantee or
even guess where individual people
will have to go or how far they'll
have to go to get to their job, so
driving to work will likely be a
part of our lives for any
foreseeable future. In fact only
tele-commuting
will likely have any impact on that.
• The
number one "user" of energy in its
creation and every day after are
"buildings." Our homes, commercial
offices, institutional, industrial,
etc. represent 40 percent of our
total ongoing energy usage and their
construction is the most resource
intensive endeavor on the planet
with supply chain impacts that add
huge multiples to energy use and
socio-economic / environmental
impacts worldwide.
•
There is
absolutely no science or any studies
that would back up the claim that
massive development can reduce
greenhouse gas emissions. In
fact even a cursory review of the
science would strongly suggest this
will actually be a NET
ADDITION to
greenhouse gas emissions over
what normal regional growth will
produce (which will be done
gradually, as needed, and
incorporate more advanced building
technologies available in the
future).
At the
risk of injecting some logic to this
discussion, ABAG / MTC are saying that
we need to promote more buildings (and
many times what we'll actually need to
meet historical growth and using
today's building technologies) to
solve climate change? (truly "green"
building technologies are not yet
commonly or economically available)
Ironically,
all the ABAG / MTC greenhouse gas
emission goals could be met by 2025 by
simply increasing our state vehicle
mileage standards by less than 5
percent! This would cost us
nothing, economically, environmentally
or otherwise. It would penalize the
source (vehicle manufacturers) and not
taxpayers and citizens who are doing
nothing more than trying to save the
communities they've worked so hard to
create.
How can you not be appalled by all
this? Why aren't any of the Marin
County Supervisors convening
town halls and community meetings to
hear what people have to say?
Our representatives (city and county)
seem paralyzed, cowering before these
quasi- governmental juggernauts,
without so much as raising their hand.
All the focus seems to be on being
polite and maintaining decorum at all
costs, science and facts be damned.
I urge you to lead not run with the
herd.
…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….
Why
“One Bay Area’s”
Growth
Plan is Not the Solution for
Marin –
Part II
The following is the
text of a follow up Op-Ed piece which
challenges the One Bay Area Plan’s
assumptions about high-density housing
and its long-term view of the
automobile. 3/8/12
In reaction to my Op-Ed piece some
people have commented that we have no
choice but to accept One Bay Area’s
vision because the urgency of our
climate change crisis demands that we
do everything we can, right now,
without hesitation. But doing
“everything we can” and doing “more of
the same” is an important distinction
we need to make.
That said, there are three things
wrong with the argument that says we
have to take action indiscriminately.
- The first is the assumption that
there is an egalitarian “we” that
can respond effectively to climate
change issues.
- The second is the assumption
that One Bay Area is a viable
solution based on the belief that
high density development reduces
greenhouse gases (GHG).
- And the third is that the
automobile is inherently evil.
Unfortunately, the first
assumption is false, the second
is not based on science or facts and
the third is just ignorance.
1. What can we do right now to
address climate change?
The truth is that while individuals
are offered very few GHG reducing
options in the basic services and
products we need to buy (and I’m not
talking about green-
washed nonsense like MEA), the real
GHG culprits (energy producers,
corporate agribusiness, transportation
manufacturers, consumer products
manufacturers and big industry)
continue to resist any changes to
their business-as-usual models.
Years of professionally managed
messaging and green-washed advertising
have “shamed” people into obsessing
about every drop of water they waste,
every table scrap that’s not composted
and every slip of paper not recycled.
This brainwashing is happily promoted
by mainstream media and quasi-public
agencies (ABAG, MTC, et al) looking to
increase their reach. It averts
attention from the real story. As a
result, many educated, well-intended,
socially conscious people are
convinced that everything is their
responsibility and the future will be
very bleak without immediately
adopting “solutions” like One Bay
Area. This is pure nonsense.
Climate change solutions need to first
and foremost address the sources of
GHGs “up the ladder” before forcing
burdensome adaptations on individuals
and small communities “down the
ladder.” What we are being subjected
to is a classic example of the old
principle that “s**t flows downhill.”
Our climate change problems are
primarily a national policy failure
which is expressed through
dysfunctional tax, subsidy and funding
mechanisms. Our federal government has
never had a national energy policy and
still refuses to cooperate with every
other industrialized nation in the
world on climate change treaties.
Taxpayers in the U.S. spend almost a
trillion dollars a year subsidizing
oil and gas (tax subsidies, program
subsidies etc.), while new energy
technologies and products wither and
die due to lack of financial support.
All of this leaves state and regional
governments in a lurch.
2 – Does high density development
near mass transit really reduce GHG
emissions?
Shockingly,
there is no scientific evidence that
proves high density development near
mass transit reduces GHG per capita
overall. In fact, “cities”
(high density taken to its logical
conclusion) are greater net GHG
producers per capita than suburban and
semi- rural communities like Marin
County. New York City, for example,
arguably the poster child for “high
density development near
transportation,” is the fifth highest
GHG producer on the planet.
High density may be “mechanically”
efficient but that isn’t the same as
being environmentally beneficial,
particularly when you include the
exogenous demands it places on
regional ecosystems. Cities with the
highest densities import more water
and power from greater distances (with
greater losses and costs along the
way) and export more GHGs because they
can’t be mitigated locally. Marin,
on the other hand, with its livable
scale and balance of developed land to
open space, produces less overall
environmental impact and
mitigates much
of its GHG output locally.
Certainly there’s more we must do but
Marin is
already possibly the best model of
sustainability we have anywhere in
this country.
3 – What about cars and trucks?
Robert Lutz, the famous automotive
pioneer and former head of General
Motors, recently said that within 10
years battery technology will have
reached a point where the internal
combustion engine will no longer be
able to compete economically with
electric powered vehicles and will
become obsolete with or without
legislation: this coming from the man
who invented the “muscle car.”
So if our cars and trucks begin to
average about 40 mpg (this technology,
hybrid or electric, is readily
available today) and more importantly,
regardless of engine type, they meet
ZEV standards (Zero Emissions Vehicle
– many hybrids already do this), the
car is no longer an important GHG
contributor. So why in the world would
we base an enormously disruptive and
expensive long-term plan, like One Bay
Area, on the premise that it is?
Onward
Imagine if property owners in
Marin had real financial and tax
incentives to install
solar panels and
small wind turbines on their rooftops,
trade up for energy-saving appliances,
use LEEDS Platinum building standards
for new construction, etc. At-the-
source solutions could cut Marin’s
energy usage and GHG output by 50
percent and possibly more. For a
fraction of the financial costs (not
to mention the social and
environmental costs) of One Bay Area’s
dark vision, we could probably exceed
their goals for 2025 by about 500
percent even with the additional
growth we actually need.
I would suggest that this is the
“everything” that we should be
promoting rather than
just more high
density and 19th century mass transit
concepts. And if you still
think “growth” and “doing more of the
same” is somehow a solution to cutting
GHGs and environmental sustainability,
consider our addiction to growth is
doing to the planet, with species
extinction accelerating, forests
dwindling, fisheries in crisis and
desertification increasing at alarming
rates, among other evidence.
No reasonable person is arguing
against any growth at all. Certainly,
mixed-use and infill housing and
higher density in appropriate settings
(as decided on a community by
community basis) are possible, perhaps
even desirable.
But please, make no mistake about it.
SB375 is not a climate change bill. SB
375 was crafted by Senator Darrell
Steinberg. The list of his top
contributors over the
years continues to be a who’s who of
financial, building, banking and other
real estate special interests.
So the next time you hear someone
telling you about the burdens we have
to bear to fix problems you didn’t
create, I would suggest that instead
of dutifully resigning
yourself to a bleak future vision like
One Bay Area, push back “up the
ladder.” Stand up to the fashionable
thinking of our times and just say
“No.”
We need to nurture and lead with
innovation and grassroots community
participation, not give up all we have
worked so hard for generations to
create. The vicious cycle of endless
growth,
urbanization and false hopes
pinned on
delusional social engineering
and central
planning have
always failed
and will always fail.
But if we act like sheep, we deserve
to be sheared.
…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….
We Don’t Want “One Bay
Area”
The following is the
text of a follow up Op-Ed piece which
challenges the fundamental concept of
the One Bay Area Plan. 3/29/12
These are uncertain times. But if
there’s one thing I’m sure of, it’s
that no one decides to live in the Bay
Area because it's "One Bay Area."
If anything, we’re the poster child
(and the butt of endless jokes) for
diversity of people, ideas and
"place."
But lately, we’re inundated with
guilt-giving Op-Ed pieces extolling
the virtues of
central planning and a
dystopian vision called the One Bay
Area Plan. It’s wrapped in
politically correct phrases like “affordable
housing” and “reducing
greenhouse gases” and comprised of
a truckload of contradictory laws,
terms and agencies like
SB375,
AB32,
RHNA, ABAG, MTC,
TAM,
BCDC, BAAQMD, PDAs, SCSs and APDs -
enough to take a thousand lawyers a
thousand years to comprehend.
This “nexus of nonsense” is the work
of prominent politicians, backed by
deep pocket
development and construction
interests, “ladder climbing” staff and
local elected officials, and a
non-stop chorus of shaming from
brown-nosing, wannabe bloggers and
agenda-driven, nonprofit academics,
funded by anti-local control social
engineers.
The only problem with this cacophony
of "smart"
growth advocacy is its
complete lack of common sense and
factual basis.
We’re told we can “build our way
out of climate change” (SB 375),
which, even disregarding for a moment
its complete lack of scientific basis,
defies even a 6th grader’s sense of
logic. We’re told that “housing is the key to
sustainability,” though all evidence
points to the exact opposite.
Truth be told,
housing has nothing to do with
sustainability, economic,
environmental or otherwise.
- Las Vegas, Denver and Atlanta
all bore the worst of the housing
bust because they
overbuilt
their real housing needs.
- Manhattan and San
Francisco have never had enough
affordable housing yet they thrive.
- The South Bronx and
Oakland have always had an
excess of affordable housing and
they continue to struggle.
From the Sumerians to the Mayans,
the real cause of unsustainability has
been resource depletion from too much
growth, as will be the case with
water
in Marin.
And who’s to say it wouldn’t be better
for the planet to build
entirely new
“green” towns hundreds of
miles north, where
a balance of
development and impacts could
be better achieved? I don’t know, but
I do know it’s not Sacramento central
planners who should decide.
But then why let facts get in the way
of a good jobs program in an election
year?
Still, even as
ABAG pressures us to build,
we’ve had the comfort of believing
that as an unfunded mandate, very
little development was actually going
to happen. However, now we have
SB 1220, brought to us by
some of the same people who brought us
SB 375 (Steinberg). It proposes
a $75 tax on recording every document
related to real estate transactions
and sends its $700 million to $1
billion a year in proceeds into a
bureaucratic black hole called the
“Housing Opportunity Trust” in
Sacramento. Decisions about how the
money is spent will now be governed
only by political agendas and big
money special interests.
SB 1220, combined with SB 375’s plan
to “warehouse”
the poor in high-density developments
next to highways and rename
open space “resource areas,” may
represent the final nail in the coffin
of local control of zoning and
property rights. Generations of
efforts to create Marin's unique
quality of life will be dismantled.
And in the end, my bet is that One
Bay Area's stillborn vision of
homogenization still won't have solved
the core problem:
providing
quality housing choices for those most
in need.
The Best Laid Plans – Appendix D
An Alternative Analysis to the
Development of Miller Avenue in Mill
Valley
This is a link to a
privately funded study that was
presented to the Mill Valley City
Council in October of 2007, but its
principles apply to all California
cities.
Read the Alternative Analysis Study
at:
http://www.friendsofmillvalley.org/files/MillerAvenuePlanAnalysisv10.pdf
59
|